Loading...
HomeMy WebLinkAboutAPA816r 1- r -r J f r J- j~ r r L L L u_ r u_ [ J'. • ., I I .. .· .! . '· Technical R~pi ort ~·. ~ St. Geo rg .e Basin Numbet ·''67 Alaska OCS , Socioeconomic .:. Studies Program. Sponsor: j Bureau of:· Land ·.· M·anagem .ent Alaska 0 ute r Continental Sheff Office Petroleum o·evelopment Scenarfos Economic. & Demographic Analysis NOV 1 1984 .l.:GASKA RF~OURC~ r;nmARY U.S. DEl'T. OF IX1Et~J.OR TECHNICAL REPORT NO. 57 CONTRACT NO. AA550-CT6-61 ALASKA OCS SOCIOECONOMIC STUDIES PROGRAM ST. GEORGE BASIN PETROLEUM DEVELOPMENT SCENARIOS ECONOMIC AND DEMOGRAPHIC ANALYSIS PREPARED FOR BUREAU OF LAND MANAGEMENT ALASKA OUTER CONTINENTAL SHELF OFFICE DOCUMENT IS AVAILABLE TO THE PUBLIC THROUGH THE NATIONAL TECHNICAL INFORMATION SERVICE 5285 PORT ROYAL ROAD SPRINGFIELD, VIRGINIA 22161 III ·: .. NOTICE · .. ···· ..; .. ,._. ~--·_., . This document is disseminated under the sponsorship of the U.S. Department of· the Interior, Bureau of Land Management, Alaska Outer Continental Shelf Office, in the interest of information exchange. The Unite.d States Government assumes no liability for its content or use thereof. ALASKA OCS SOCIOECONOMIC STUDIES PROGRAM· ST. GEORGE BASIN PETROLEUM DEVELOPMENT SCENARIOS ECONOMIC AND DEMOGRAPHIC ANALYSIS . Prepared by Bradford·H. Tuck and. Lee·Huskey Institute of Social and Economic Research University of Alaska April 1981 IV ·····-·---.... --- · •.. -"! .. [ [ [ l-· ~~ L -. r L. [ c .lJ [ E r, I L [ ..,----...--.--,.·-··-· ·-"'"-· ·----~·--·-· --~--------~-----·~------ j -> TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES LIST OF FIGURES . INTRODUCTION .. -·., -.· ... STATEWIDE AND REGIONAL GROWTH: THE BASELINE HISTORICAL ANALYSIS . The Statewide Economy: Statehood -1978~ ..•.•• Regional Economies: Anchorage, Southcentral, and. Southwest The·Aleutian Islands Census Division. • •••. THE BASE CASE. • . • • . . . • • Non-OCS Base Case Assumptions: MAP Models •...•......• The Base Case Assumptions . . . Non-OCS Base Case Assumptions: SCIMP . . .. .. . .. . . • .. ·-. . . • . The Base· Projections. • . . . . • The Base Case: Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest Regions -• . . • •. Base Case Projections: SCIMP and the Aleutian IsJands Census Division ..••• PROJECTED IMPACTS OF THE ST. GEORGE BASIN SALE Introduction. • ~ ' • . • .: • •· . . • • • • • • • . • . The Mean Case· Scenario:. Statewide Impacts . . • . • Impacts of the Mean Case Scenario on the Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest Regions. The Low (Exploration Only) Case Scenario: Statewide and Regional Impacts ...... . The Mean Case Scenario: The Aleutian Islands Census Division Impacts ..•.•..•... The Low Case Scenario: The Aleutian Islands Census Division • • . . • . • • . . . . • . ' APPENDIX A: COMPUTER PRINTOUT OF LOW CASE IMPACTS, . STATEWIDE AND REGIONAL. APPENDIX B: FISHERIES ASSUMPTIONS. . ••••••• v . . . . •· -. . . . . IV IX 1 3 32 41 73 83 84 100 104 120 131 137 137 139 160 175 178 184 189 231 APPENDIX C: OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN. APPENDIX D: OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT BY PLACE OF WORK AND REFERENCES • BY PLACE OF RESIDENCE: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN . 0" • • • • ·-• • -: •• ·0 0 • • 0 • 0 • VI • • • 249 25l 257 [ [ l-, [ [ -f-, L [ I' t~ [ c [j [ [ [ LIST OF TABLES vn ~ C":".t•:-__ __::..:.:=---~-=----==---:-:-_:._ ___ .. _-..::::=_-__:_:_:-___ ::-_.~-:=-~:=-~:~-~~~--""""""= ·-'"'-=-""'--··---~'~~----· --~ ------ 16. Shellfish Harvest, by Area, Selected Years 1962-1976 17. Residence of Boats and Gear License Holders Fishing the Aleutians • 18. Military and Related Federal-Civilian Employment and Wages, Aleutian Islands Census Division, 1978 19. Average Civil ian Monthly Employment Aleutian Islands Census Division, 1965-1978 .•. 20~ Aleutian Islands Census Division Estimated Resident and Nonresident Employment, 1978 •...•.•. 21. ·Aleutian Islands Census Division: Civilian Resident Labor Force, Total Employment, and Unemployment 1970-1975 ••••••••.••••••. 22. Report of Labor Force 1978 Compiled by Bureau of Indian Affairs ·Anchorage Agency ••.• 23. Personal Income by Place of Residence: Aleutian Islands Census Division, 1965-1978 ..•••• 24. Aleutian Islands Personal Income, 1978-by Place of Work and to Place of Residence •••••••• .. 25. Family Income: Number and Percent of Native and White Families by Income Levels Aleut Corporation Area. • •••••.•.•• .26. Aleutian Islands Civilian and Total Resident Population: 1960, 1970-1978 •••• _ • 27. Aleutian Islands: Components of Population Change, 1970-78 • • • • • • • . • • • 28. Aleut Region Population by Community, 1977 . ....... 29. Scenario Economic Assumptions •••• 30. 31. 32. Resident Employment in Fisheries Projected Employment in Fisheries and Construction Aleutian Islands Census Division: 1980-2000. Projected Population and Components of Change: Alaska, 1980-2000 .•.. VIII 45 47 52 54 56 59 61 63 65 68 70 71 72 88 93 103 105 [ [ [ r L [ [ [ b c [ L r . L I . L~ L ... l j j j 33. Projected Employment: Alaska, 1980-2000 •• 34. Projected Total and Per Capita Real Personal Income: A 1 as ka ,, 1_980-2000. . • • 35. Projected Wages and Salaries: Alaska, 1980-2000 36. Projected Real Wage Rates: Alaska, 1980-2000 •• 37. Projected Alaska and U.S. Price Indexes: 1980-2000. 107 • 109 111 • 113 • 114 38. Projected State Government Revenues: Alaska, 1980-2000 ..• 116 39. Projected Total and Per--Capita State Government Expenditures: Alaska, 1980-2000. 40. Projected Fund Balances. in Current and 1980 Dollars: Alaska, 1980-2000 •••••. 41. Projected Regional Population: 1980-2000 •. . .. . . 42. Projected Regional Tota-l Employment: 1980-2000 •. 43. Projected Regional Support Sector Employment: 1980-2000. • . •.• 117 • 119 • • 121 • 123 124 44. Projected Regional Government Employment: 1980-2000 •..• 125 45. Projected Regional Basic Employment: 1980-2000 ••. 46. Projected Total Personal Income by Region: 1980-2000. 127 128 47. Projected Per·Capita Regional Personal Income: 1980-2000. 129 48. Aleutian Islands Census Division Employment Projections:. 1981:-2000 .••••• -49. Aleutian Islands Census Division: SCIMP Population Projections, 1981-2000 . . 50. Projected. Statewide Population Impacts, Absolute Values: ·Mean Case . . . . . . 51. Projected Statewide Population Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case. . 52. Projected Statewide Employment Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ........ . IX •· . . . 132 . . •· . . . . . 135 .. ·-. . . . . . 140 .. . . •· . . . . 141 . . . . . . . . 143 53. Projected Statewide Employment Impacts, ·Percentage Differences: Mean Case. 54. Projected Statewide Real Personal Income Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ••.••••• 55. Projected Statewide Real Personal Income Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case ••••• .56. Projected Statewide Real Wage and Salary Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ••• ~ .•.• 57. Projected Statewide Real Wage and Salary_ Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case •• -58. Projected Statewide Real Wage Rate Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ••.••• 59. Projected Statewide Real Wage Rate Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case •••. 60. Projected Statewide Relative Price Index Impacts, Absolute and Percentage Differences: Mean Case 61. Projected Statewide Revenue & Fund Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ••• · •• 62. Projected-statewide-Revenue & Fund Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean ·case .• 63. Projected Statewide Real Government Expenditure Impacts, 144 146 147 149 • • 150 152 153 154 156 157 Absolute Va 1 ues :. . Mean Case • . • • • • . • • • • . . 158 54. Projected Statewide Real Government Expenditure Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case ••••• ~ • • • • 159 . 65. Projected Regional Population Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean·-Case • ·.• • ·~ • • • •. . • • • • • • • • 66. Projected Regional Population Impacts~ Percentage Differences: Mean Case • • • • • ••• 67. Projected Regional Total Employment Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case .....• 68. Projected Regional Total Employment Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case .•. 69. Projected Regional Basic Sector Employment Impacts, • 161 162 164 165 Absolute Values: Mean Case •.••••.••....•.. 167 x· ~~ .... --.... ~--·-·· ~ .................. -. -----....,.---~-----:-·:.---·----.....-----~--,..-.. ~ ----_--:--~-~---·----.~--~:-~· ~-=--~:···_ ... ·-:·:·'"· [ [ t~ [ -·-[ ·. ---·--·~ ----,;. [ [ [~ ... · -~ ,~ L [ [ [ r:' b_) b [ L \I I ~ 70. ProjectedRegional Basic Sector Employment Impacts, Percen.tage Differences: Mean Case. • . • • • . 71. Projected Regional Support Sector Employment Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case •.••••.••• 72. Projected Regional Support Sector Employment Impacts, 168 169 Percentage Differences: Mean ·Case. . • • • • ·170 73. Projected Regional Government Employment Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case .••••.•• 74. Projected Regional Government Employment Impacts, · Percentage Differences: Mean Case ••... 75. Projected Regional Real Personal Income Impacts, Abso 1 ute Va 1 ues: · Mean Case • . • • • • • • 76. Projected Regional Real Personal Income Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case •.••• 77. Projected Regional Real Per Capita Income Impacts, Absolute Values: Mean Case ..•.••.••• 78. Projected. Regional Real,.Per Capita Income Impacts, Percentage Differences: Mean Case •••.•• 79. Projected Changes· in Resident and Total Population Mean Case, Aleutian Islands Census Division: 171 172 173 174 176 . . 177 1981-2000 • • . • .• • • • • . . • • • . • . . • ~ • 179 . 80. Projected Changes in Resident and Nonresident Employment, Mean Case, Aleutian Islands Census Division: 1981-2000 • • -• • . • • • . • • • • • • . • . • . • • 182 81. Projected Changes in Resident and Total Population, Low Case, Aleutian Islands Census Division: 1981-1988 • .. • • • . • • • • • • • • . . • • • .• · 185 82. Projected Changesin Resident and Nonresident Employment, ·Low Case, Aleutian Islands Census Division: 1981-1988 • • • .. • • • . • • • • • . • . • • • . . 186 XI .;!-!_··· ~· .•. """" • •. -• • --· ~-· ....... ----------~~--':"..---...-,;'~~~:. ~~:---,., .. -..,.;.,. ... ~ ..... --· .. -.:-~--~--~----..... -· ., -·----:--·--.-----~---,--.. ---~----------~-----------~-~,.-.... - _ LIST OF FIGURES 1. Distribution of Wage and Salary Income Alaska, 1965 and .1978 • 2. -MAP Sub-Mode 1 s • • • 3. MAP Statewide Model ••• 4. MAP Regions •••••••• XII 28- 75 78 80 [ [ [ .. [ -_ r· ... L [ [ [ [ -c ';6 [ [·: ·" r· L r- L L I. INTRODUCTION The present study provides the historic baseline analysis and base case projections against which the economic effects of the proposed St. George Basin OCS lease sale are measured. The analysis and projections .~re carried out at the statewide level and for selected regions within th~ st~te economy. The regions include the Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest regions of the Man-in-the-Arctic Program (MAP) models. In addition, the baseline analysis and projections have also been carried out at the subregional level for the Aleutian Islands Census Division. In this instance, projections have been made utilizing the Institute's .Small Community Population Impact Model (SCIMP). Part II of the study contains the historical baseline analysis for each of the economic areas in question and generally focuses on specific economic an.d demographic concerns relevant to an understanding of the historic growth of.the economies~ The baseline analysis also assists i.n laying the foundation for assumptions regarding future growth of the areas. Particular emphasis has been placed on the analysis of th~ Aleutian Islands Census Division for two reasons. First, this is the first ISER-OCS lease sale analysis which has called specifically for study at the census division level. Second, and more important, is the fact that the Aleutian Islands Census Division can expect the greatest relative (although perhaps not absolute) impact resulting from the proposed OCS sale. Part III contains three important elements. First, the underlying pro- jection methodology is explained and reviewed in terms of the accuracy and limitations of the projection methodology and the projections them- selves. Second, the assumptions necessary to 11 drive 11 the models a.re presented. Finally, the base case projections for the respective areas are presented. Part IV of the study presents a description and analysis of the pro~ jected impacts associated with the proposed St. George Basin sale. Results for the mean an9 low case scenarios .are discussed, both at the statewide and regional levels. Supporting materials are contained in the appendices. 2 ··-··---------· ·-----·---·· ------· --------·-· -·-·------·--·----------.-....... ___. ... - [ [ [ [ [ [ [ c r L [ ~ c [ b [ [ r· L r L _J II. STATEWIDE AND REGIONAL GROWTH: THE BASELINE HISTORICAL ANALYSIS The Statewide Economy: Statehood -1978 In carrying out the historic baseline studies,. either for Alaska or .the regions, it is important to keep in mind the purpose of the analysis. There are three pr 1 imary objectives involved. , , I First, the analysis should provide the uninitiated reader with a general sense of the structure of the economy and how and why it has changed over time. Second, the study should provide some indication of how individuals within the system have benefited from the functioning of the system; i.e., an assessment of economic well-being. Third, the baseline history should provide guidance in developing assumptions regarding future development of the economy. Hence, the historical baseline study is not simply a description of the economy, but rather provides an analysis of the growth and changes in the system, the dimensions of economic well-being, and its future pros- pects. With these comments in mind, we can now turn to the baseline study of the state as a whole. At the risk of oversimplification, the economic history of Alaska can be summarized as one of resources, defense, disaster, more resources, and. government. Prior to World War II, interest in the state focused largely on natural resource exploitation, primarily based on furs, fish, and hard. rock minerals. World War II and the cold war aftermath lead to a sizeable military-government involvement in the state, both in terms of population and economic activitY~ 3 The advent of statehood found an economy reflecting a narrowly based private sector~ largely dependent upon limited natural resource activity, and a. large federal civilian and military presence. In 1960, for example, federal civil ian wages and salaries accounted for 25 percent of~ the total civil ian wage bill, while state government (5.9 percent) and local government (5.1 percent) made up an additional 11 percent of total wage and salary payments. When military payrolls are included, 42.5 percent of wage and salary income was accounted for by government. Discovery of the Swanson River oil field in 1957 had done much to raise expectations about future economic prospects, but it was not unti 1 major discoveries in Cook Inlet during 1965 that the oil and gas industry became firmly established and significant levels of production were assured. The·emergence of petroleum resources as a significant factor in the Alaska economy considerably improved the potential for private sector development and, more importantly, helped to shore up the extremely . shaky fiscal base of· state government. For the mid-and latter part of the decade of the 1960s, it was to be natural disaster that provided much of the impetus for economic growth. The Good Friday earthquake of 1964 resulted in a major reconstruction effort which supported levels of economic activity that probably would not have been achieved otherwise. A second disaster, of lesser statewide magnitude but of great consequence for the Fairbanks region, was the flood of 1967. Disaster relief and reconstruction funds, followed later by flood control projects, provided a needed boost for the region's economy. 4 [ L [ [ C [ r~, u [ L r· L r~ L _j j Discovery of oil at Prudhoe Bay in 1968 marks the beginning of the latest phase of Alaska economic history. Development of the supergiant field, construction of the oil pipeline, and the related flows of reve- nue to state government are providing the impetus for sustained economic growth and diversification that should carry the state well into the- 21st century. 'I\ Against this backdrop, we can now look more specifically at several important dimensions of growth and change in the Alaska economy. As suggested earlier, there are certain key measures of economic activity that are central to the analysis. Personal income and employment data provide insight into the overall growth of the economy and changes in the composition of economic activity. In addition, these data can be used as general indicators of changes in ·economic well-being over time~ An important corollary variable is population growth. It is also instruc- tive to review aggregatemeasurs of production for the economy. In addition to these general measures of economic activity, there are· several specific attributes of the economy that need tobeconsidered. These include such topics as secular and seasonal unemployment, the structure of costs and prices, and the role of state government with respect to determining overall economic activity. Finally, we must consider-issues related to potential future economic activity~ We now turn to speci ftc measures of the economy. 5 PRODUCTION Data measuring the gross value of production by industrial ·Classification are not available for recent years. However, various measures of the value of output for selected industries have been compiled and are pre- sented in Table l. Except for agriculture, the industries reflect the, primary 11 export base 11 components of the private sector economy. Data on federal and total government expenditures have also been included for comparative purposes. Furthermore, a large portion of federal government outlays indirectly reflects an export of goods and services by th~ private sector economy of Alaska. Fisheries and petroleum have clearly dominated growth in the value of production in the private sector. Value of catch to fishermen has grown at an average. annual rat~ of 15 percent over the period, and wholesale value has grown almost.as rapidly (14.4 percent), reflecting both the substantial growth of shellfishing and rising product prices. When deflated by the co·nsumer price index (which is appropriate if we are interested in implicit purchasing power), the value of catch grew at almost 10.3 percent and the wholesale value by 9.5 percent. Crude oil and natural gas percentage growth rates are relatively meaningless since the base in 1960 is negligible, but their· significance is obvious. It is also worth noting that in 1978 (the last year for which data are available) production of minerals other than oil and gas and sand and gravel amounted to 18.4 million dollars, or about 0.6 percent of the total value of mineral production. Neither has there been any signifi- cant change in the value of this dimension of mining over the past two 6 c [ [ '[ [ I' L ·[ [ [' L [ [ [ [ L [ [ r L r. L L l. l. . _j . .,; \._' ,J Table 1. Value of Production for Selected Industries Various Years, 1960-1979 (millions of current dollars) Federal Total l Industry Agriculture Forestr~ Fisheries Oil &.Gas Government Government i Value to Fishermen Wholesale Crude Dry Outlays in ·Spending in I Year Salmon Shellfish Total Value Oil Gas Alaska (FY) Alaska (FY) I ' ! I l 1960 5.6 47,3 33.6 3.1 40.9 96~7 1.2 .03 155.8 N.A. l I 1961 5.7 48.0 35.7 5.1 46.5 128.7 17.7 .129 N.A. N.A. 1962 5.7 52.3 42.1 7.1 58.4 131.9 31.2 • 467 N.A. N.A • 1963 5.3 54.1 31.3 9.6 46.9 109.0 32.7 1.1 N.A. N.A. 1964 5.6 61.0 41.4 10.0 56.8 140.9 33.6 1.7 N.A .. N.A. ,, 1965 5.3 57.5 48.3 14.5 70.1 166.6 34.1 1.8 533.7 N.A. ·I I I 1966 5.3 71.2 54.2 17.6 81.9 197.3 44.1 6.3 N.A. N.A. i 1967 5.2 80.6 24.6 18.3 48.8 126.7 88.2 7.3 N.A. N.A. l :J '-I 1968 4.9 89.2 49.5 27.9 79.9 191.7 186.7 4·:_4: N.A. N.A. l 1969 4.3 101 .0 40.6 20.8 68.1 144.2 214.5 r2.1 N.A. N.A. 1970 5.2 93.7 68.0 20.5 97.5 213.9 232.8 1.8.2 728.7 N.A. I 1971 5.0 103.5 51.4 26.0 85.5 198.7 234.3 18.0 852.9 N.A. I i 1972 6.0 82.3 45.3 33.6 92.4 185.7 221.7 18.0 989.4 N.A. 1973 7.0 131.4 60.1 61.4 142.4 283.0 239.6 19.5 1018.6 1592 1974 8.1 154.7 65.7 62.8 144.8 254 347.4 22.5 1135.9 1730 1975 9.2 133.5 55.3 55.4 129.4 293 364.6 42.8 1326.8 2000 1976 8.8 149.5 118.0 96.5 . 239.6 452p 318.8 60.5 1368.1 2226 1977 9.9 179.3 171 l57p 349p 723 988.9 66.6 1544.9 2524 1978 9.2p N.A. 238p 272p 543p 1118~ 2701. 5p 89.6 1753.0 2845e 1979 9.1 N.A. 317p 231 606 1243 5493.6 91.5 1932.2 3147 p =preliminary e = estimate N.A. = not available SOURCE: See;Table 1 Notes Table l Notes I The data are primarily obtained from selected tables i"n The Alaksa Economy: Year-End Performance Report 1978 (Alaska Department of Commerce and Economic Development, Division of Economic Enterprise;· Juneau, Alaska) and Alaska Statistical Review (Alaska Department of Commerce and Economic Development, Division of Economic Enterprise; Juneau, Alaksas 1980). The latter source is a preliminary report. Specific-sources for each column · of the table follow. Agriculture: page B-13 Alaska Statistical Review (ASR). Value of sales is approximately 74 percent of value of production, with the balance being used on farm. Forestry: Data from 1960-1971 are from Alaska Statistical Review (1972), p. 90, and reflect total end product value. For 1972-1977, the data are from the 1978 Year End Performance Report and reflect only forest prod- uct exports. Here the series are not comparable, but individually reflect growth in the periods in question. Comparable series are not available over the full period. Fisheries: Data for 1972~1975 are from the 1978 Year End Performance Report, p. 58. 1976 data are from Alaska Catch and Production: 1976 (Alaska Department of Fish·and Game). 1977-1979 data are from ASR (1980). 1960-1971 data are from ASR (1972) p. 74. Data for 1960-71, 1976-79 are comparable. Data forl972-75 represent approximately 92 per- cent of total wholesale ·value. · Oil and Gas: ASR (1980) p. B-3. It should be noted that these data do not include value added in transportation and here reflect approximate wellhead value. Federal Government Outlays in Alaska: 1960-1977 data are from 1978 Year End Report,. p. 105. 1978-1979 data are from ASR (1980), p. E-2. Data are for fiscal year ending in given calendar year. · Total Government Spending in Alaska: Data from ASR (1980) p. E-1. The total is net of intergovernmental transfers. 8 [ [ [ [ l l_. [ [ r' I -L [ [ [ L r L r L t decades. In deflated dollars~ federal government expenditures have grown at about 9.3 percent. Government expenditures are not directly comparable to the value of .production in other industries since they reflect not only government production (wages. and salaries) but purchases of). goods and services and ' ·. I \ transfer· payments to individuals. However~ in another sense these expend1tures do reflect a measure of demand for production of goods and services throughout the economy as a whole and underscore the continuing importance of government spending in the economy. Of particular significance in overall government spending is the role of state government spending. The state fiscal history can roughly be divided into three periods: early post-statehood~ Prudhoe Bay sale to pipeline completion, and Prudhoe Bay production. During the· first period, federal government grants., both statehood tran- sition grants and others, were an important component of state government revenues. The re 1 ati ve· decline in federa r grants were more than offset by revenues linked to general economic growth and the development of Cook Inlet petroleum resources~ but expenditures were constrained by available revenues. The $900 million Prudhoe Bay lease sale in the fall of 1969 ushered in the second period and led to an immediate doubling of state government expenditures. Growth in expenditures continued rapidly, although still 9 constrained by avqilable revenues and the rapidly diminishing balance of '• the lease sale. The third period is marked by the commencement. of pro- duction from Prudhoe Bay; and, for the first time, the state has signi- ficant potential surplus revenues.· The rapid expansion of revenues since 1969 has resulted in a closely correlated growth of state government expenditures. This is reflected not only in expanding state government employment and wages but also by total government expenditures for purchases of goods and services and transfers to local government. The net result has been that state government spending (both directly and through local government) has assumed a significant role in the overall determination of economic activity in Alaska. This is a pattern which will prevail for some time into the future. In summary, the role of natural resources in the growth of the Alaska economy has been dominated by fisheries and petroleum. Forest products have remained regionally important, primarily for Southeast Alaska, but have not demonstrated significant growth. Agriculture has remained stagnant, and, in real terms, the value of production has declined. Government has remained a major force in the economy, with state and local government increasing in relative proportion to total government. EMPLOYMENT, UNEMPLOYMENT, AND WORK FORCE Analysis of employment, unemployment, and work force,data is important for several reasons. First, since labor is one of the key factors of 10 [ [ [ [ [ [ [ 1: L r L [ c [ [ [ [ I~ L r L E I I I· production, employment data provide a general indicator of the growth and composition of production over time. The main deficiency with these data for such purposes is that they ignore changes in factor proportions over time and differences in factor proportions between industries. This omission is particularly important in industries that are-highly ·capital-intensive, such as the petroleum industry. Also, siry_C:e these . , 'I\ data are based on job counts, they do not reflect actual man hours of production and, hence, provide only an approximate measure of labor input.· Second, work force data, in conjunction with total employment data, determine unemployment. It is instructive to observe the patterns of unemployment over time and in response to changes in total economic activity. Third, the data are useful in measuring seasonal patterns of economic activity and how this may have changed over time. Tables 2 and 3 provide summary data on employment, labor force, and unemployment for selected years over the 1960-1978 period.· Total em- ployment over this period grew at an annual average rate of 4.9 percent. However,. substantial variation in the growth rate is evident. From 1960- 1973, the rate was 3 percent; while for 1974-1978 (reflecting the pipeline boom) the rate was 8.6 percent. The growth of the civilian labor force shows a similar pattern, although increasing at a slightly higher rate . . . The result of this is that total unemployment has grown at about 7 percent per year over the period and the unemployment rate has also increased. 11 . . -·--............ ·-.-------.. -----------. _ ___,_ ___ ,__,...._.. ___ ~ c~----· ·--.. .,., ... 4 ____ _. -·~·-·--.....--·---..--:· ····--···-· ----... ----• Total Civilian labor Force Total Unemployment % of Tot<t1 Labor Force Total EmploymEmt Non-Agricultural Wage and Salary Employment Mining ~ Contract Construction !\) Manufacturing Food Processing Log9ing, Lumber, Pulp TABLE 2. CIVILIAN EMPLOYMENT, UNEMPLOYMENT, AND LABOR FORCE 1960, 1965, 1970-1978, BY BROAD INDUSTRY CLASSIFICATION (in thousands) 1960 1965 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 . 1975" .. ....... 1976 73.6 5.9 8.0% 67.7 89.8 7.7 8.6% 82.1 91.6 6.5 "7 .1% .S5.J 97.7 8 •. 0 8.2% 89.6 103.6 8.6 8.3% 95.0 109.1 9.3 8.5% 99,9 125.6 9.9 7.9% 115.7 156.0 10.8 6.9% 145.3 168.0 14.0 8.3% 154.0 1977 174.0 16.0 9.2% 158.0 1978 181.0 . 20.0 11.0% 161.0 ~;_% __ ._%_~._% __ ._%_~._% __ ._%_-._% __ ._%_~_% __ ._%_~._%_ 56.9 100.0 70.5 100.0 92.5 100.0 97.6 100.0 105.4 100.0 111.2 100,0 129.7 100.0 163.7 100.0 173.5 100.0 166.0 100.0 163.2.100.0 1.1 1.9 1.1 1.6 3.0 3.2 2.4 2.5 2.1 2.0 2.0 1.8 3.0 2.3 3.8 2.3 4.0 2.3 5.0 3.0 5.6 3.4 5.9 10.4 6.5 9.2 6.9 7.5 7.4 7.6 7.9 7.5 7.8 7.0 14.1 10.9 25.9 15.8 30.2 17.4 19.5 11.7 12.2 7.5 5,8 10.1 6.2 8.8 7.8 8.4 7.8 8.0 ~.1 7.7 9.4 8.5 9.6 7.4 9.6 5.9 10.3 . 5.9 10.9 6.6 11.5 7.0 2.8 4.9 3.0 4.3 3.7 4.0 3.6 3.7 . 3.7 3.5 4.6 4.1 4.3 3.3 4.3 2.6 5.1 2.9 5.5 3.3 6.3 3.9 2.2 3.9 2.3 3.3 2.8 3.0 2.8 2.9 2.8 2.7 3.2 2.9 3.6 2.8 3.4 2.1 3.2 1.8 3.5 2.1 1.8 1.1 Transportation, Communications Public Utilities 6.8 12.0 7.3 10.4 9.1 9.8 9.8 10.0 10.0 9.5 10.4 9.4 12.4 9.6 16.5 10.1 15.8 9.1 15.6 9.4 16.4 10.0 Trade Finance, Insurance, Real Estate Services Government Federal State Local 7.7 13.5 10.0 14.2 15.4 16.6 16.1 .16.5 17.1 16.2 18.3 16.5 21.1 16.3 "26.2 16.0 27.6 15.9 28.5 17.2 28.8 17.6 1.4 2.5 2.2 3.1 3.1 3.4 3.2 3.3 3.7 3.5 4.2 3.8 4.9 3.8 6.0 3.7 7.1 4.1 7.8 4.7 8.2 5.0 5.6 9.8 7.5 10.6 11.4 12.3 12.5 12.8 14.0 13.3 15.2 13.7 18.3 14.1 25.1 15.3 27.7 16.0 27:4 16.5 27.6 16:9 22.7 39.9 29.7 42.1 35.6 38.5 38.0 38.9 41.7· 39.6 42.8 38.5 45.3 34.9 49.5 30.2 49.7 28.6 50.7 30.5 52.2 32.0 15.6 27.4 17.4 24.7 17.1 18.5 17.3 17.7 17.2 16.3 17.2 15.5 18.0 13.9 18.3 11.2 17.9 10.3 17.7 10.7 18.1 11.1 3.9 6.9 7.0 9.9 10.4 11.2 11.7 12.0 13.3 12.6 13.8 12.4 14.2 10.9 15.5 9,5 14.1 8.1 13.9 8.4 14.3 8.8 3.2 5.6 5.3 7.5 8.1 8.8 9.0 9.2 11.2 10.6 11.9 10.7 13.1 10.1 15.8 9.7 17.6 10.1 19.1 11.5 19.8 12.1 Table 2 r-fdtes Sources of data: 1960, 1965 ASR (1972) p. 16. It should be noted tha.: the "labor force 11 data are actually work force data for these two years and are not directly comparable with the data for 1970-1978. The basic difference between the two series is that work force estimates are based on job counts and, hence, a worker may be counted more than once if holding two or more jobs. Labor force estimates are supposed to eliminate this double counting. Thus, the· work force data for 1960 and 1965 somewhat overstate the actual number of employed. In 1970-1978, labor force and total employment estimates are obtained:, from Alaska Labor Force Estimates by Area (Alaska Department of Labor), various years. Non-agricultural wage and salary data are obtained from the Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor) for the various years. 13 .... ~ ·-·---~---.,...-....,_,., __ ··-· --.. ---~~-·-----.--·---. ~-···---·-- \ il TABLE 3. INDEX OF SEASONAL VARIATI,ON IN NONAGRICULTURAL EMPLOYMENT: SELECTED YEARS 1960-1978 .. "1960 1965. 1970 1972 1974 Total Nonagricultural Employment 39.4 30.6 22.7 24.6 32.0 Contract Construction 156.2 91.7 69.5 77 ~6-108.2 Manufacturing 136.3 116.3 107.9 105.2 70.8 1976 23.1 . 64.7 78.2 Food Processing 211 .5 195.2 196.3 175.3 100.6 112.0 Trade . 20.8 20.0 15.6 14.8 25.1 13.5 Services 28.4-17.2 10.7 16.2 26.8 13.3 _Unemployment Rate, All Industries . 117.5 74.4 59.2 65.1 82.3 45.8 labor Force · 28.2 26.5 21.8 21.0 27.1 21.2 1978. 14.0 47.2 86.5 125.0 12.0 17.8 20.0 12.0 SOURCE: Compiled from Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor), selected years. Seasonal variation is measured as the high month ·minus the low month divided by average annual figure, stated as a percent. Unemployment data are from labor Force Estimates (Alaska Department of labor), various years. 14 [ [ [ [ [ ·[ L [ [ L [ L c C L [ [ r: L r L [ 1 j j j It is also worth noti'ng· that during the pre-pipeline period the unemploy- ment rate was relatively stable and that the somewhat higher rates of 1977 and 1978 reflect in large part a readjustment to a more normal post,-pipeline period. These data c1 early i 11 ustrate the openness of the Alaska labor market.. Large variations ir:t the demand for labor are pri .. marily met by significant in-and out-migration and by changes in labor force participation rates. As a consequence, the long-run rate of unem- ployment is quite stable and the simple expansion of economic activity has little effect in terms of reducing unemployment. The second block of data in Table 2 provides annual average e~ployment data by broad . . industry classification. In addition to illustrating the sustained growth of employment and production in all industry categories, these data also indicate relative changes in the significance of specific i ndustri es • Employment in mining: 1s the one basic sector industry that has increased . its share of total employment • .-The federal government share has declined substantially over the period, while both state and local government have grown, with much of the growth in state government employment occurring during the 1960s and the early 1970s. Local government growth . . lagged state government in the early years, but by 1975 local government employment exceeded state government employment. Of particular interest is the growth of support. sector activity, including trade, finance, insurance and real estate, and services. This growth reflects a steady diversification of support sector activity and the process of import substitution in response to increasing market size, growth of incomes, 15 and opportunities for spec;ializatiori. general maturation of the economy. In short, the data reflect a I It is also of interest to consider changes in seasonal patterns of . economic activity. Table 3 summarizes seasonal activity in selected industries, as well as for total nonagricultural wage and salary employ- ment, labor force, and unemployment. Seasonal variation is measured as the high month minus the low month divided by the average annual figure for the: respective variable. Because of secular growth in the variables, the index tends to overstate seasonality for any given year, but for comparative purposes, over time, the index is satisfactory. The data reflect two important dimensions of the Alaska economy. First, seasonality v.aries drastically from industry to industry, with construe-· tion and manufacturing (especially food processing) showing the greatest seasonal swings. Second, while significant se~sonality remains in all industry,. there has been a major reduction over time. In summary, the data on labor force, employment, and unemployment illus- trate several important features of the Alaska economy .• First, while growth has been uneven, aggregate economic activity has increased sub- stantially since statehood. Contract construction, mining, and support sector industries· grew rapidly during pipeline construction. With the exception of contract construction, levels of employment achieved at the peak of pipeline construction have generally been sustained or have increased. 16 [ [ ~ [ ·····[ r·· l __ ..... [ -~ L~ [ L [ [ c C L [ L l L L ., -., ., Second, structural change that refl'ects a general maturing of the economy has 'occurred,. as evidenced by the increased share of total employment accounted for by support sector activity, including trade, finance, insurance and real estate, and services. Coupled with the greatly reduced dependence of the state on federal goyernment activity and the growth of petroleum and fisheries, the data indicate a general broaden- ing and diversification of economic activity. Third, in addition to sustained secular growth, there has been a marked dec~ease in seasonal swings in economic activity. In part, this reflects the relative growth of industries with smaller seasonal variations. In addition, construction and fish processing seasonality have also reduced substantially. Finally, the relative stability of unemployment rates over time clearly indicates the openness of the Alaska labor market. The generally higher than national average' unemployment rates have not responded to aggregate economic expansion historically and probably will not in the future. PERSONAL INCOME Personal income measures that part of the total value of production that accrues to individuals and includes: wage and salary income; other labor income; proprietor's income; income from dividen4s, interest, and rent; and personal transfer payments. While deficient in many respects as a measure of economic well-being, it is nevertheless a useful indicator of the degree to which individuals share in the total benefits of production. 17 Table 4 presents estimates of personal income for Alaska, by major source, for selected years covering the period from 1960 through 1978. Personal income has grown steadily over the entire period, at an average annual rate of 11.3 percent, while for the pipeline period the growth was about 17 percent per year. Wage and salary income accounted for the majority of personal income throughout the period, averaging 80 percent • . In contrast, about 68 percent of U.S. personal income is accounted for by wages and salaries. Proprietor income as a share of total personal income has declined somewhat; while that of dividends, interest, and rent has increased modestly. The share accounted for by transfer pay- ments has increased substantially but still remains well below the national figure of 12.6 percent. The data also generally confirm the relative changes in the composition of industry activity that were observed in the employment data. The growth of aggregate personal income in Table 4 reflects not only aggregate growth of production but also the influence of inflation. Table 5 presents aggregate personal income in both current and constant dollars. Growth of constant dollar personal income has been significant and has averaged 7.8 percent per year. During the 1974-1977 period, the growth was even more dramatic at 11.8 percent in real terms. The com- bined effects of inflation and the plateauing of economic activity follow- ing completion of pipeline construction have resulted in a slight decline in real personal income in.l978. 18 [ [ [ [ [ [~ [ [ [ L [ c c [ c [ [ f' L r· L [ ; \ l. " . j l.. . . .J L. ...... J lL. .. J ~ ..... J t .. '· J l. . .J l ., .J L. . J j L . TABLE 4. PERSONAL INCOME BY MAJOR COMPONENT: ALASKA, SELECTED YEARS 1960-1978 (millions of current dollars) 1960 1965 1970 1975 1978 COMPONENT ~ % Total $ % Total $ % Total $ % Total $ % Total Wages & Salary 567.9 84.1 778.2 88.8 1293.9 84.7 3620 85.0 3954.9 80.6 Private, Total 281.5 41.7 463.2 52.8 773.1 50.6 2771 65.1 2907.2 59.2 Mining 10.3 1.5 14.3 1.6 54.2 3.5 116 2.7 248.4 5. 1 Contract Construction 77.3 11.5 98.0 11.2 140.2 9.2 1095 25.7 537.8 11.0 Manufacturing 47.1 7.0 59.7 6.8 90.9 5.9 161 3.8 260.9 5.3 Fisheries 17.7 Z.6 22.9 2.6 31.4 2.1 46.2 1.1 100.5 2.0 Forest Products 8.4 1.2 22.8 2.6 38.6 2.5 64.8 1.5 50.0 1.0 _, Support Sector 142.1 21.1 265.3 30.3 457.4 29.9 1364 32.0 1817.0 37.0 1..0 Government 286.6 42.5 376.0 42.9 593.6 38.8 993 23.3 1301.8 26.5 Federal Civilian 104.7 15.5 137.6 "15. 7 195.1 12.8 308 7.2 383.2 7.8 Military 136.0 20.1 143.9 16.4 225.7 14.8 258 6.1 287.5 5.9 State & Local 45.9 6.8 94.4 10.8 172.9 11.3 427 10.0 631.0 12. 9. - Proprietors• Income 50.1 7.4 62.1 7.1 73.9 4.8 143 3.4 . 260.5 .5.3 Dividend, Interest & Rent 33.0 4.9 52.1 5.9 81.4 5.3 220 5.2 333.4 6.8 Transfer Payments 24.0 3.6 34.2 3.9 79.3 5.2 274 6.4 358.3 7.3 TOTAL 675.0 100.0 876.6 100.0 1528.5 100.0 4257 100.0 3907.1 100.0 Less Cont. for Soc. Ins. 11.0 22~3 49.2 172.0 223.5 Residence Adj. 31.5 45.9 67.1 637.0 314.6 Resident Personal Income 632.5 900.2 1412.2 3447.0 4369.0 Table 4 Notes SOURCE: Major components of the table are obtained from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis reports of personal income by state. Wages and salary figures (row 1) include wage and salary plus other labor income components of personal income. Except for 1960, the private, total row and subcomponents thereunder, contain wage and salary income, other labor income, and proprietors' income. Total income is the sum of the wages and salary row plus proprietors' income; dividends, interest and rents; and transfer payments. Resident personal income is equal to total income less contribution for social insurance.and the residence adjustment. 20 [ [ [ [ r· [ [ [ L [ [ c c L [ [ [ ' L l ~ ' J __;, . ~ ~ ~ ~ - = j 1960 1965 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 . 1976 1977 1978 TABLE 5. ALASKA RESIDENT ADJUSTED PERSONAL INCOME IN CURRENT AND CONSTANT 1979 DOLLARS 1960, 1965, and 1970-1978 Millions of Dollars of Personal Income, Total Per Ca~ita Personal Income Current $ Constant 1979 $. Current $. Constant 1979 $ •'. 1 632.5 1,470.6 2.,79l 1 1 6,503 858.4 1,982.8 3' 168 7,318 1 ,411 . 9 2,700.3 4,644 8,882 1 ,557. 2 2,954.8 4,939 9,372 1 ,698. 5 3,036.4 5,234 9,631 2,001 .5 3,570.0 6,046 10,784 2,436.7 3,822.9 7,138 11 '199 3,527.7 4,493.5 9,673 12,321 4 '194. 8 5,421.4 l 0,274 13,278 4,313.4 5,346.5 10,455 12 ,959 4,369.0 4,875.2 10,849 12 '1 06 Average Annual Percent Growth 11.3 7.8 6.9 . 3. 5 SOURCE: Current dollar personal and per capita income from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Deflated by Anchorage Consumer Price Index, U.S. Department of Labor. 21 There are two other dimensions of personal income that are particularly I . important in assessing individual economic well-being: per ··capita income and the distribution of income. Table 5 includes data on the growth of per capita personal income in real and current dollars. Real per capita income from 1960-1973 grew at an average annual rate of 4 percent. The 1973-1978 period, encompassing pipeline construction and the post-boom readjustment, shows rapid expansion until 1976 and then a substantial drop during 1977 and 1978 •. The net growth over the period is only 2 percent per year. Two points are worth noting in this respect. First, the rapid expansion of activity occurred during a period of high national inflation and was of sufficient magnitude to lead to additional regional inflation in the Alaska economy. Thus, the real value of per capita income growth was greatly diminished. Second, the rapid expansion of total economic activity had only a minimal effect in raising per capita income, again reflecting the ease of entry into the Alaska labor market. Data on the distribution of personal income are not available for recent years, but it iY instructive to look at the pattern of wages over time. Table 6 presents data on relative wages, by industry, for selected years over the 1965-1978 period. The numbers reflect the ratio of the average monthly wage for the respec- tive industry divided by the average monthly wage for all nonagricultural wage and salary employment. The data must be interpreted with caution since severai factors are at work that may account for year-to~year 22 [ [ [ [ [ [ [ [ [ c c c I' L L TABLE 6. DISTRIBUTION OF RELATIVE WAGE RATES~ BY INDUSTRY, FOR ALASKA, SELECTED YEARS~ 1965-1978 Industry . 1965 1970 1976 Total Nonagriculture Wage and Salary 100 100 100 Mining 147 164 140 Contract Construction 165 169 210 I\ Manufacturing 106 99 73 . Food Processing 97 78 55 Logging, Lumber, and Pulp 115 124 96 Other Manufacturing 112 110 83 Transportation, Communication~ and Public Utilities 115 114 105 Wholesale Trade 127 117 94 Reta i 1 Trade 78 70 50 Finance~ Insurance~ Real Estate 88 81 62 Services 74 72 78 Government 91 97 74 Federal 91 100 70 State 91 96 79 Local 91 93 72 1978 100 193 157 93 71 119 109 128 111 62 81 75 97 94 111 89 SOURCE: Computed from average monthly wage data from the Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor), selected years. Relative wages are the respective industry wage divided by the average wage for all industries x 100. 23 variability. First, the average monthly wage data reflect both straight time and overtime earnings and are thus sensitive to variation in the ratio of straight time to overtime \<Jork. Second, the average monthly wage is computed by di·viding total wages by average monthly employment~ and average monthly employment, in turn, reflects both full and part-time work. Thus, the employment data are only an approximation of man hours worked. We are also looking at fairly aggregate data. Some of the variation within industries may be .. , accounted for by changes in composition of activity within the broad industry classifications. The data first indicate the growing disparity of average wage rates, which would suggest a trend toward a less equal distribution of income. More significant are the changes th~t occurred at the peak of pipeline construction in 1976. Major distortions in the structure of wages are present, and this ~uggests that the distribution of benefits during a boom is not uniform, but rather that a small segment of the economy appears to reap a large proportion of the gains. This feature of boom economics is further demonstrated by an analysis of changes in real wages over the 1973-1976 period. Table 7 shows average monthly wages, by broad industry classification, deflated by the Anchorage consumer price index (CPI). Use of the Anchor- age CPI is dictated because there is no statewide index. Hence, the deflation is subject to some error since price changes are not uniform throughout Alaska. As an approximation, however, the data are adequate. 24 I I __ , [ r· L L ~ cl '1 J ..l ~ ' ..l ~ - _. I: /• TABLE 7. CHANGE IN REAL AVERAGE MONTHLY WAGE 1973-1976~ ALASKA (1973 DOLLARS) Average Wage Average Wage Industry 1973 . 1976 Total Nonagricu1ture Wage and Sa 1 a ry $1 ~006 $1,424 Oil and Gas Mining 1~661 2~068 Contract Construction 1 ~635 2,985 Manufacturing 961 1~041 Transportation, Communication, and Public Utilities 1 ~ 141 1~494 Wholesale Trade 1 '177 1~341 Retai 1 Trade 687 709 Finance, Insurance, Real Estate 897 884 Services . 751 1,107 Hotels~ Motels, Lodging 527 537 Business Services 732 1,706 Government 1 ~024 1~047 Federal 1,062 .1,002 State 992 1 '132 Local 1,003 1~024 Average \.-Jage Percent Change 12.3% 7 .6· .. .22.2 2.7 9.4 4.4 1.1 -0.5 13.8 0.6 32.6 0.7 -1.9 4.5 0.7 SOURCE: r.omouted from averaae monthlv waae data. Statistical Quar.terlv ~~l~~~a-Dep~rtment ~f Labor): sei~cted ;ears. 25 U.S.. DEPT. OF INTERIOR I\ It is clear that drastic differences exist among industries and that the economic benefits of rapid economic expansion tend to be concentrated in a select few industries. A major portion of income implied in the growth of construction wages was also earned by nonresidents or temporary resi- dent employees. With the exception of business services, all components of the support sector and government badly lagged the average growth of · wages and, implicitly, relative income. Federal government and finance, insurance, and real estate real wages actually declined. While much of the inflation that occurred during the period is attri- butable to national inflation, significant regional inflation resulting from pipeline construction activity also occurred. Prior to pipeline construction, the Anchorage CPI had been growing at a less rapid rate than the U.S.·CPI. Howe·ver, during pipeline construction, this relation- ship was reversed, and the Anchorage CPI grew more rapidly. Table 8 presents relative rates of growth in the Anchorage and U.S. CPis for selected years and clearly illustrates the regional inflation associated with pipeline construction. As one final indication of income distribution patterns, a distribution relating percentage of total wage and salary income to percentage of employment has been constructed for 1965 and 1978 (see Figure 1). The distribution was constructed by ranking industries according to average monthly wage. The percentage of total employment and total wage income accounted for by the respective industry \'las then computed. The cumulative 26 [ [ [ [ [ [ 1: L [ r~ L ,. L r· L .[ Anchorage United States TABLE'. 8. RATES OF CHANGE FOR THE ANCHORAGE AND U.S. CONSUMER PRICE INDEX~ SELECTED YEARS~ 1960-1977 1960-1970 1970-73 1973-74 1974-75 1975-76 1976-77 1.8 .4. 1 13.3 12.3 6.5 5.8 2.8 5.6 12.0 7.6 5.3 6.5 SOURCE: Derived from the Bureau of Labor Statistics reports on Anchorage and United States CPis. 27 Percent of FIGURE 1 . DISTRIBUTION OF WAGE AND SALARY INCOME ALASKA, 1965 and 1978' 901---------------------------------- so-·-··· · ·· · ·-·····-·· -··---------· .. ------· 70-: .. ·~·-·-~· .. ·." ................ .. n li ;r ~ 'I ----· ---ij I . ---, 'f .·-···-.. -··· u I ---1 j i i 6o-----.. ·7 -··-·--------------......... -· ... _ .. _ ···--................................ ---· •. .. _______ .. ____________ 1 t Wage & Sa 1 ary 50 __________ ;_:__ ____ --/!. l Income l 4o-------------C...--, -... ·--, --.. :· . ··_-I 3o~-·--.. ·-------................... -~----·-----·-----~ -····-· 2o-------.. ..,. .. -. ------~'-"'-"'' · · 0 1.-_.=::...:.J ~~ •. :.J ... .l _ . ..... .I .. -~----L . . ... . l 40 50 60 70 10 20 30 Percent of Employment SOURCE: See text. 28 -~---l .... ·: _·__ t I I J. . . . _.I .. ~~:;-:. I 80 90 100 [ ~ [ ,~ l. '·' [ ,- l. r· I L li' I . L r L:.: [ [ [ B [ [ r·, L r. I L [ employment and income percentages were then plotted, yielding the typical Lorenz-type distribution figure. A comparison of the two distributions reveals a clear shift toward a less uniform distribution of income. This shift is probably accounted for by two factors. First, as indicated earlier, there has been a siz- able increase in the share of total activity accounted for by support sector industries, and these industries generally have lower than aver- age wage rates. Second, there has been a substantial growth in the range of relative wages between industries over time. In summary, real personal income has shown sustained growth over the entire 1960-1978 period, both in aggregate and per capita terms. The growth has not been uniformly distributed, however, and the wage compo- nent has become less uniform over time. This was particularly evident during pipeline construction and supports the hypothesis that the bene- fits of pipeline construction were largely concentrated in a few sectors. POPULATION The remaining dimension of growth to be considered is population. Changes in population are divided into two components, natural increase (or decrease) and in/out-migration. Natural population growth results from an excess of births over deaths and is, hence, determined by birth and death rates. 29 *'· . Alaska exhibits both the highest birth rate and the lm•Jest death rate in the United States; and as a result, the rate of natural population increase is the highest in the United States. This phenomenon is largely accounted for by the relative youthfulness of the population, with over 34 percent of the population between the ages of 14 and 30. This age group has both the highest ferti 1 i ty rate and the 1 owest death r·ate. Net migration (in-migration minus out-migration) is the second factor contributing to population change. Many factors influence the migration decision; but for the Alaska case, it appears that (with the exception of military-related migration) migration occurs largely in response to economic opportunity. In the aggregate, relative rates of unemployment and relative wage differentials in Alaska and elsewhere should be impor- tant in determining the migration decision. At the individual level, the economic component of the decision is related to the expected gain resulting from the move. Basically, this is the expected wage differ- ential times the probability of getting a job, less the cost of making the change. Thus, either a change in relative wage rates or relative employment ppportunities can influence the decision. That migration is sensitive to economic opportunity is clearly demon- strated by patterns of migration that occur during and after pipeline construction. Data summarizing population and changes in population for Alaska for the years 1965 through 1978 are presented in Table 9. Both the relative stability of natural increase and the volatility of net migration are clear. Natural increase has averaged about 1.5 percent 30 ,~ L L L [ [ [ [ 6 [ [ f ' L ': I• TABLE 9. ALASKA POPULATION AND COMPONENTS OF CHANGE: 1965-1978 (thousands) Year Total Natural Increase Total Change Net Migration 1965 265.2 5.7 10.2 4.5 1966 271.5 5.3 . 6.3 1.0 1967 277.9 5.0 6.4 1.4 1968 284.9 5. 1 . 7.0 1.9 1969 294.6 5.6 9.7 4.1 1970 302.4 6.1 7.8 1.7 1971 312.9 5.9 10.6 4.7 -, 1972 324.3 5.5 11.4 5.9 1973 330.4 5.1 6.1 0.9 :::; 1974 351.2 5.6 20.8 15.2 1975 404.6 5.9 53.4 47.5 -' 1976 413.3 6.3 8.7 2.4 1977 411.2 6.8 -2.1 -8.9 1978 407.0 6.7 -4.3 -11.0 SOURCE: Alaska Department of Labor 31 per year; while large variations, even in pre-pipeline years, are evident in the net migration component. In summary, Alaska's natural population growth is substantially above that of the nation as a whole. Furthermore, the response of migration to economic opportunity is clearly evident. Once again, this emphasizes the openness of the Alaska labor market. Regional Economies: Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest Potential impacts of OCS development will not be uniformly felt through- out the State. Rather, specific regions within Alaska can be expected both to experience the brunt of the impacts and to capture dispropor- tionate shares of the benefits. In the case of the present proposed lease sale, the Anchorage and southcentral regions can expect impacts as well as the southwest region, within which the sale would occur. Hence, the baseline analysis must address these regions as well as Alaska. ANCHORAGE Anchorage has occupied a central role in Alaska's growth since state- hood. It has emerged as a key transportation and distribution center, as well as assuming a dominant role in the growth of other support sector activity. The area has also become the State center for petro- leum industry administrative facilities. Its importance as a seat of Federal government activity in Alaska has been supplemented by rapid growth of State and local government. Because of the size of the Anchorage economy, it tends to reflect total State activity as well as 32 [ [ [ f' L [ [ [ L [ [ r, L f' L [ to impact upon total economic activity in Alaska. It is because of its central place in the Alas~an economy that economic activity ·remote from Anchorage is often significantly tied to Anchorage. Employment, Labor Force, and Unemployment Direct measures of production for the Anchorage economy are not avail- able. Neither is Anchorage a-commodity producer in which resource-based activity is directly important to total economic activity. This makes it particularly important to consider the structure and growth of employment for Anchorage. While such data are only partially reflective of total production, they do provide meaningful insights into changes that have occurred. Summary data on Anchorage employment, by broad industry classification, for 1965 through 1978, are presented in Table 10. Overall employment has grown at about 7.3 percent per year, and the rate of growth exceeded the statewide rate of 6.7 percent. While growth has generally been consistently upward, it accelerated substantially during pipeline con- struction. Since then, growth of employment has moderated; but the level of employment still exceeds that achieved during the period of pipeline construction. It is also worth noting that, in contrast to other parts of the State where pipeline construction played a signifi- cant role in the expansion of activity, Anchorage growth during this period occurred more uniformly throughout most sectors, reflecting the region•s role as a support center. 33 1965 ~ ! Total NonAgric Wage & Salary. Employment 30.678 100.0 Mining 0.371 1.2 Contract Construction 3.126 10.2 Manufacturing 0.791 2.6 w Transportation, ..j::o Communications, and Utilities 2.618 8.5 Who 1 esa 1 e-·Retai 1 5.279 17.2 Finance, lnsur- ance and Real Estate 1.295 4.2 Services 3.767 12.3 Federal Government 9.394 30.6 State & Local Government 4.001 13.0 SOURCE: Statistical Quarterly TABLE 10. ANCHORAGE NONAGRICULTURAL WAGE AND SALARY EMPLOYMENT, SELECTED YEARS (thousands) 1968 1970 1972 1974 ~ ! ~ ! ~ ! ~ ! 34.019 100.0 42.019 100.0 48.252 100.0 58.713 100.0 0.781 2.3 ·. 0.958 2.3 0.806 1.7 1 .036 1.8 2.438 7.2 3.514 8.4 4.272 8.9 5.882 10.0 0.834 2.5 1.018 2.4 1.215 2.5 1.379 2.3 3.046 9.0 3.907 9.3 4.522 9.4 5.583 9.5 6.552 19.3 8.617 20.5 9.948 20.6 12.298 20.9 1.452 4.3 1.980 4.7 2.415 5.0 3.151 5.4 4.652 13.7 6.403 15.2 7.725 16.0 10.119 17.2 9.216 27.1 9.534 22.7 9.435 19.6 9.925 16.9 5.022 14.8 6.036 14.4 7.839 16.2 9.242 15.7 (Alaska Department of Labor), various years. 1976 1978 ~ ! ~ ! 73.733 100.0 76.893 100.0 1.409 1.9 1.874 2.4 7.587 10.3 6.431 8.4 1.629 2.2 1.683 2,2 7.409 10.0 7.950 10.3 15.958 21.6 16.865 21.9 4.257 5.8 5.019 6.5 15.450 21.0 15.538 20.2 9.813 13.3 9.896 12.9 9.465 12.8 11.266 14.7 . ·-.. --~ . ·-· ----· . ... -.... ----·---·· ... ·-··-·-----------·-·· ···-······ ····--· .... -. ---------------··-·········-·--·--. ·-.-• • ··•••-•• ·-·-·" •-._~---• ,_,_ r•••--• -••·-<-•-••" -·--· ·---• • • "• --•••-•• • • ,, ••-•• ----L ~ ,....---, ''" ·" ": . J r-----l \ J r~, Several industries expanded more rapidly than the growth of total empToy- ment, including: mining (13.3 percent); transportation, communications, and public utilities (8.9 percent); wholesale-retail trade (9.4 percent); finance, insurance, and real estate (11.0) percent; services (11.5 per- cent); and State and·local government (10.5 percent). Construction, manufacturing, and Federal government growth rates were all below the regional average for the period. The growth of the support sector illustrates the maturing of the Anchorage economy as was also observed at the statewide level. A comparison of statewide and Anchorage support sector employment as a percent of total employment also indicates the role of Anchorage as a trade, distribu- tion, service, and financial center for the State as a whole. Employ- ment as a percentage of total Anchorage employment considerably exceeds comparable figures at a statewide level in trade, finance, and services. For Anchorage, these industries accounted for 48.6 percent of total employment in 1978; whereas for the State as a whole the figure is only 39.5 percent. The share of total employment accounted for by the Federal government in Anchorage is also above the State proportion, and over 50 percent of total Federal government employment in Alaska is based in Anchorage. The data on labor force and unemployment also illustrates the openness of the Anchorage economy (see Table 11). Over the period from 1970 through 1979, unemployment a'·araged 7.4 percent. While temporarily dropping during pipeline construction, the unemployment rate has risen 35 Year 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 TABLE 11. ANCHORAGE LABOR FORCE, EMPLOYMENT, AND UNEMPLOYMENT, 1970-1978 Employment Labor Force Unemployment Unemployment Rate 45,757 49,024 3,267 6.7% 49,484 53,902 4,418 8.2 52,395 57,535 5,140 8.9 54,299 60', 117 5,818 9.7 54,691 58,661 3,970 6.8 64,721 68,481 3,760 5.5 68,420 73,436 5,016 6.8 79,023 84,513 5,490 6.5 74,819 81,551 6,732 8.3 75,424 81,120 5,696 . 7.0 SOURCE: Alaska Department of Labor, Labor Force Estimates by Area, selected years .. 36 [ -[ L L ·] ' [' [ [ r~ L [ E [ [ t= [ [ r~ L again to historic levels in the years since completion of the pipeline, averaging 7.7 percent for 1978 and 1979. Hence, while rapid expansion of employment opportunities may temporarily reduce unemployment, the effects are clearly short-run. Personal Income Total and per capita personal income for Anchorage are shown in Table 12, both in current and constant (1978). dollars. In current dollars, both total and per capita personal income have grown every year (at average annual rate of 14.4 percent and 10.0 percent, respectively) with con- siderable increases in the rate occurring during pipeline construction. Much of the growth has· been negated by inflation, however. In real terms, total incomes grew at 8.2 percent over the period; while per capita income grew at 4.1 percent. However, both real total and per capita personal income have declined slightly since peaks reached during pipeline construction. It is also worth noting that the growth rates of Anchorage personal income exceeded those of the State for comparable periods. Population Population for Anchorage has grown from 102.3 thousand in 1965 to 185.5 thousand in 1978, at an average annual growth rate of 4.7 percent (see Table 13). This was substantially in excess of the statewide growth rate of 3.4 percent. As a result, the Anchorage share of total State population rose from 38.6 percent in 1965 to 45.6 percent in 1978. From 1965 to 1969, the Anchorage and statewide populations grew at about 37 I' ~ 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 TABLE 12. ANCHORAGE PERSONAL INCOME 1965-1978 Current Dollars. Constant (1978) Dollars Total Total (mi 11 ions) Per Capita ·(millions) Per Capita 371 3,412 767 7,056 398 3,595 722 7,153 462 4,061 900 7,911 502 4,228 953 8,027 570 4,622 1,035 8,391 635 4,997 1 '109 8,730. 733 5,469 1,248 9,313 800 5,631 1,333 9,383 880 6,031 1,385 9,490 1 , 114 7,402 1,550 10,299 1,625 10,070 2,011 12,463 1,903 10,579 2,212 12,296 2,109 11 ,592 2,317 12,736 2,128 11,839 2,128 11 ,839 Average Annual Percent Growth 14.4% 10.0% 8.2% 4.1% SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. 38 [ r [ r' [ [ [ [ ~~ L [ [ [ [ b [ [ F L f' L [ _ _; ---' TABLE 13. ANCHORAGE POPULATION 1965-1978 (thousands) 1965 102.3 1966 105.9 1967 107.8 1968 111.6 1969 114.2 1970 126.3 1971 135.8 1972 144.2 1973 149.4 1974 153.1 1975 177.8 1976 185.2 1977 195.8 1978 185.5 SOURCE: Alaska Department of Labor. 39 ............ -. ~. ,_.--~·. . - the same rate; while for 1969-through the start of pipeline construction, the population of Anchorage grew at about 6 percent. Durin~ this period, the State as a whole grew at about 3.6 percent. Both the State and Anchorage populations grew rapidly during the 1974 through 1976 period (17.7 perp~nt an·d 20.1 percent, respectively), but the Anchorage popula- tion did not peak until 1977; whereas the statewide population reached a peak in 1976. However, the decline in Anchorage population has been proportionately greater than that for the State as a whole. In 1978, statewide population was 6.3 thousand below the pipeline peak; while the Anchorage population was 10.3 thousand below its peak. In summary, the Anchorage economy has shown substantial growth over the entire period reviewed. Steady diversification of the economy is evident, and the role.of Anchorage as an economic center for the State is clear. Furthermore, economic activity remote from Anchorage is nevertheless often s1gnificant for the Anchorage economy because of Anchorage 1 s central role. The southcentral economy includes primarily the Kenai-Cook Inlet, Seward, Matanuska-Sustina, Valdez, Chitina, Whitter, Kodiak, and Cordova-McCarthy Census Division. Economic ties exist between the Kenai-Cook Inlet, Seward, and Matanuska-Susitna Census Divisions and Anchorage. Anchorage is the primary distribution point for commodity flows to those areas. Second, the Anchorage population utilitizes the surrounding areas for recreational purposes. Finally, the surrounding areas (and in particu- lar the Matanuska-Susitna Valley area) constitute an important component 40 L L [ [ 6 [ [ r· L r. I L L of the Anchorage labor pool. More broadly, the southcentral region as a whole constitutes a labor pool for economic activity throughout the State. This last tie is the most significant in terms of linkages between the proposed OCS lease sale and the southcentral regional economy. The southwest region is the area that will be directly impacted by the proposed St. George Basin sale. The region includes the Kuskokwim, Wade Hampton, Bethel, Bristol Bay; and Bristol Bay Borough Census Divisions, as well as the Aleutian Islands Census Division. Because the area most directly linked to the proposed sale is the Aleutian Islands Census Division and because links with other areas within the region are negligible, we focus our attention on the Aleutian Islands Census Division. The Aleutian Islands Census Division The Aleutian Islands Census Division encompasses all of the Aleutian Islands, the Pribilof Islands, and the Alaska Peninsula from Port Moller west. The census division is also a subregion of the southwest region of the MAP model. The economy of the Aleutian Islands Census Division in no sense reflects a cohesive, functional economic area. This economic area is composed of several relatively isolated communities and Federal government military installations. Private sector activity is almost totally dependent upon utilization of the abundant fish resources and includes both harvesting 41 --·-·· =--·--·~.,:.·.~----~---~--·--. ·-····---------~.- and processing. Harvesting of fur seals on St. Paul Island is also an important local activity. Minor amounts of sheep ranching ··also occur in the region. Military installations at Shemya and Adak, as well as .elsewhere in the region, swell the population, employment, and income figures for the census.~ivision but have no perceptible links with other economic units within the census division. PRODUCTION Basic sector ·private production is mostly composed of fisheries-related activity. Both commercial fishing and processing are widely dispersed. throughout the region, although processing is more highly concentrated in the eastern portion of the census division. Tables 14 through 16 provide summary data on commercial fishing. In Table 14th~ salmon, shellfish, total catch, and value of catch to fishermen are indicated for recent years .. The data clearly show the rapid increase in both the value and volume of shellfish harvested in the region. A longer-run view of shellfish harvest is shown in Table 15 and highlights the growth in the diversity of shellfish caught. In particular, both tanner crab and shrimp have provided much of the growth in the shellfish harvest, helping to offset significant declines in king crab catches that occurred during the late 1960s and early 1970s. Finally, Table 16 provides data on the disparities of catch within areas of the region and how these have changed over recent years. Significant declines in king crab harvests in all areas are noted, with the exception of the Bering Sea which has more than offset the declines in other areas. Tanner crab 42 [ [ [ [ L [ [ [ [ [ [ L [ l r: L [ ' TABLE 14. CATCH AND VALUE TO FISHERMEN, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION 1970 TO 1976, SELECTED YEARS (catch in million pounds; value in million dollars) Year Salmon Shell fish Tota1 1 Pounds Value Pounds Value Pounds 1976 20.910 7.155 154.262 61.032 175.921 1973 . 6.993 1 .815 60.966 25.135 71.261 1970 28.695 5.102 44.082 9.108 74.540 1Totals include minor amounts of other fish. There is also an unreconciled discrepancy for the weight of shellfish in Table 14 and Table 15 for 1973. SOURCE: Alaska Catch and Production (Alaska Department of Fish and Game, Division of Commercial Fisheries), selected years. Data prior to 1970 not available on a comparable basis. 43 Value 69.029 29.243 14.793 Year 1962 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 . TABLE 15. SHELLFISH HARVEST, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION, 1962, 1965-1976 (millions of pounds) Kingcrab Dungeness Tanner Shrimp 6.840 ,, I 50.704 .017 63.993 .025 .000 .000 61.990 .000 .003 .000 53.060 .953 .142 4.375 39.895 1 .380 1.662 2.657 35.408 . 717 3.558 4.399 53.997 .022 2.307 5.228 52.957 .000 4.054 14.891 56.620 .201 6.183 18.947 66.812 .061 13.998 31.245 70.002 .004 12.592 20.504 82.943 .000 30.202 41.117 Total 6.840 50.717 64.018 61.993 58.530 45.594 44.082 61.554. 71.902 81 . 951 112.116 103.102 154.262' SOURCE: Alaska Catch and Production: Commercial Fisheries Statistics (Alaska Department of Fish and Game, Division of Commercial Fisheries), various years. Areas included are South Alaska Peninsula, Aleutians East-Unalaska, Aleutians West-Adak, and Bering Sea. These boundaries are not strictly comparable to the census division boundaries, but are adequate for pres- ent purposes. 44 [ [ [ [ [ [~ [ [ [ [ [ [ b [ [ r, L r· L -, ..., --' ... ' =' -, ' "" _3 _,; TABLE 16. SHELLFISH HARVEST~ BY AREA, SELECTED YEARS 1962 -1976 (millions of pounds) South Peninsula Year King Crab Dungeness Tanner Shrimp 1967 16.9 .0 1972 4.2 3.9 14.8 1976 .7 7.3 37.4 Aleutians East-Unalaska Year King Crab Dungeness Tanner Shrimp 1967 27 .l 1972 10.7 .0 . 1 1976 11.4 .5 3.7 Aleutians West-Adak Year King Crab Dungeness Tanner Shrimp 1967 12.5 1972 16.2 1976 .4 .1 Bering Sea Year King Crab Dungeness Tanner Shrimp 1967 4.4 1972 21.9 . l 1976 70.4 22.3 Area Totals S. Peninsula Al euti ans-E. Aleutians-W. Bering Sea Year Total % Total % Total % Total % 1967 16.9 27.8 27.1 44.5 12.5 20.5 4.4 7.2 1972 22.9 31.8 10.8 15.0 16.2 22.5 22.0 30.6 1976 45.4 29.4 15.6 10.1 .5 .3 92.7 60.1 SOURCE: Alaska Catch and Production (Alaska Department of Fish and Game, Division of Commercial Fisheries), selected years. 45 Total 16.9 22.9 45.4 . Total 27.1 .10.8 15.6 Total 12.5 16.2 .5 Total 4.4 22.0 92.7 Total 60.9 71.9 154.2 and shrimp have been increasingly important for the south Peninsula and Aleutian-East areas. In short, major changes in the pattern of harvests, both regionally and by species, have occurred. The south Peninsula,apd Bering Sea areas ' show overall gains and the Aleutian-East and Aleutian-West areas show net declines. These patterns are also indicated by the percentage shares of total shellfish harvest shown in Table 16. A second, important dimension of understanding commercial fishing in the Aleutian economy is an analysis of who does the fishing. Data on this point is fragmentary and is presented in Table 17. The king crab arid shellfish industry tends to be dominated by nonresident boats and crews, and the area of concentration for these vessels is the Bering Sea. Much of the remainder of the catch is accounted for, by Kodiak- based boats. The information on the salmon harvest is even less precise since the region covered is southwest Alaska (the Aleutian Census Division plus Kodiak). It is assumed, with some uncertainty, that the regional pro- portions apply to the Aleutians. The overall picture that emerges is one in which the bulk of the com- mercial fishing in the Aleutians is carried out by fishermen and vessels which are not resident to the Aleutians. More· precise information would [ [ [ I_. [ l_ ~ [ r I~ [ ~ [ [ [ [ [ I- be desirable but is simply not available. L, f ' 46 L L ., TABLE 17. RESIDENCE OF BOATS AND GEAR LICENSE HOLDERS FISHING THE ALEUTIANS Proportion of King Crab Catch Value by Boat Residence Place Percentage Kodiak 26.8 Alaska.Peninsula 4.0 Dutch Harbor 4.3 Out of State 64.9 Proportion of Salmon Catch by Residence of Gear License Holder Place Percentage Kodiak 41.5 Aleutians 20.0 South Central Alaska 3.2 Anchorage 2.6 Other Alaska 7.1 Non-resident 19.2 Unknown 6.5 SOURCE: King Crab: Western Alaska King Crab: Draft Fishery Management Plan (North Pacific Fishery Management Council, Anchorage; Council Review Draft, May 1980). Derived from data on page 30. Salmon: Derived from Table 9-8, Measuring The Socioeconomic Impacts of Alaska's Fisheries, by George W. Rogers, et al, (Institute of Social and Economic Research;· April 1980). 47 A final dimension of commercial fishing to be considered is that of employment. No systematic, periodic estimates of commercial fishing employment are made for the Aleutians (nor for the rest of the State). Estimates for the 1969 through 1976 period, however, have been compiled · for the State and regions (Rogers, 1980) and in turn have been1 used to estimate employment in the Aleutians for 1978. This has resulted in an estimate of 756 for average annual employment in commercial fishing. Of these, 251 are estimated to be residents of the Aleutian Islands Census Division. The procedure used to develop these estimates was to compute the ratio of the 1978 to 1976 catch, by species (salmon, shellfish), and apply this ratio to the Rogers• estimates of employment for 1976. Since his employment estimate was·for the southwest region, it was then necessary to allocate to the Aleutians the total employment thus estimated. This was accomplished by apportioning total employment on the basis of Aleutian to total southwest region catch and implies uniform productivity through- out the southwest region. The result of these manipulations is an esti- mate of total Aleutian Islands commercial fishing employment. The estimate of resident employment was developed using ratios presented in Table 17. It goes without saying that these estimates of employment are very approximate and subject to considerable error. The second major component of the fishing industry in the Aleutians is processing. The present structure of the processing industry reflects a mix of shore-based and floating processors engaged in canning and 48 I I I. ~- r-, I L. [ [ r, ~ - [ -L-~ -~ . " [ [ J L [ .., freezing. The trend is toward freezing an increasing proportion of the catch. A tally of processor permits for 1980 compiled from Alaska Department of Fish and Game records indicates seven shore-based facilities at Dutch Harbor; two at Sand Point; and one each at King Cove, False Pass, Squaw Harbor, and. Port Moller. Some of these permits may cover firms that are only buying fish for transshipment. Several floating processor permits are held as well: Dutch Harbor (4), Sand Point (1), and False Pass (1). In addition, some 31 permits are held that allow for floating processors to operate throughout the regior .. Not all permit holders necessarily utilize their permits, and several may actually be nothing more than buyers. It is clea'r, however, that ' processing is geographically well dispersed throughout the Aleutians. Employment data for processing is available for the Aleutians Census Division from the Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor') . For 1978, 1,621 was the average annual employment in manufacturing, which for the Aleutians is largely synonymous with fish processing. As is the case with commercial ~ishing, it is important to determine what propor- tion of the employment was held by residents of the region. Data regarding this question are fragmentary. In conversations with industry and local government people, it was estimated that somewhere between 5 and 15 percent of the employment was held by residents. A 49 second source of information is The Recommended Community Development Plan: City of Unalaska, Alaska (Trick, Nyman, and Hayes: November 1977). According to this study, 72 out of 875 basic sector jobs (1976) were held by residents, and these jobs were primarily in· fish processing. This would indicate that about 8.2 percent of processing jobs were held , ! by residents. Community profiles prepared by the Arctic Environmental Information and Data Center for King Cove, False Pass, and Akutan also contain data that tend to support the above sources regarding resident to nonresident ratios. Using what appears to be a reasonable estimate of the ·resident share of processing jobs, 10 percent, then 162 of 1 ,621 jobs were held by residents. The remainder (1 ,459) were held by nonresidents. Of these, almost all were from outside of Alaska. Significant seasonal variation exists in processing employment, although to a much 1 esser degree than is generally the case in the salmon industry. For 1978, average employment for the four quarters was, respectively: 1,255 (January-March), 1,782 (April-June), 1,649 (July-September), and 1 ,798 (October-December). The low first quarter, followed by substantial gains in the second through fourth quarters, is typical of recent years. Available data do not indicate how seasonal patterns may vary between residents and nonresidents. The second element of basic sector production in the Aleutians is Federal government and national defense-related activity. Major installations 50 L [ r l~ L [ [ [ L [ [ r--: L ! : I L [ i are located at Adak, Shemya, and Cold Bay. The largest of these is the naval station at Adak. According to data supplied by the Office of Information, Alaska Air Command, there are 1,781 active duty military and civilian defense-related personnel at Adak, as well as 1,400 depen- dents. These figures do not include additional civilian personnel associated with nondefense activity such as officers' clubs, post- exchanges, etc. Shemya and Cold Bay do not have resident dependents, and military and civilian defense-related personnel number approximately 490. Table 18 summarizes military and related federal civilian employ- ment data for the census division as a whole for 1978. While the military presence is numerically large, its economic impact Od the economy of the Aleutians is negligible. The units are largely self- supporting and the only identifiable ties with the Aleutian or Alaska economy are transportation services provided by Reeve Aleutian Airways (RAA) and some contract construction. One benefit that does result from the military contracts with RAA is the feasibility of providing more frequent air service to other communities in the Aleutians. Contract construction work at the military installations is generally carried out by non-Aleutian based firms, either from Alaska or out-of-state. In summary, basic sector production in the Aleutians is almost entirely related to fisheries resources or Federal government military-relat~:d activity. Fisheries activity has shown substantial growth but is still largely dominated by non-Aleutian resident participants. The military presence, while substantial, has no significant relationships with the rest of the census division. 51 TABLE 18. MILITARY AND RELATED FEDERAL-CIVILIAN EMPLOYMENT AND WAGES, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION, 1978 . Employment Wages (thousands) Mi.litary and Related Civilian Employment Military Personnel (Active Duty) Military-Related Federal Civilian Employment PX and NAF (Largely Part-time)1 Other Military Related Federal Employment 3,939 3,453 486 330 156 45,952 38,950 7,072 1,875 5,127 1Post exchange and nonappropriate fund activities, including officers' clubs, etc. SOURCE: Numbers: Basic Economic Statistics of Alaska Census Divisions (Alaska Department of Commerce and Economic Development, Division of Economic Enterprise: November 1979). 52 [ r t . Li [ [ [ c 6 [ [ r· L r. L [ _j _j I EMPLOYMENT, UNEMPLOYMENT, AND LABOR FORCE Analysis of employment in the Aleutians is important for the same reasons that it·was important at the statewide level. Table 19 summarizes average monthly employment for the Aleutian Census Division for the years 1965-1978. Over the period, total employment has grown substan- tially at an average annual rate of 5.9 percent. This growth has been largely dependent upon growth of the fisheries industry and State and local government. Employment in fish processing grew at an average annual rate of 14.1 percent, while State and local government grew at a rate of 8.5 percent. Federal government employment, primarily related to national defense, fluctuated considerably over the period but has shown no appreciable growth. The same is true for contract constructior. and transportation, communications, and public utilities. The support sector components of wholesale-retail trade; finance, insurance~ and real estate; and services have also expanded as would be expected. Finance, insurance, and real estate grew at an average annual rate of 18.9 percent, although much of this growth occurred after 1973. Services grew at·22.7 percent over the period, but this growth rate must be inter- preted with caution. The data for early years were not reported in the Statistical Quarterly (the source document) because of disclosure rules and, hence, were estimated. The large variation in this series also raises the question of inconsistency in the data, possibly due to -classification difficulties. Independent series on wholesale and retail trade are not available for the entire period. For those years in which retail trade data were 1965 1966 Industry Construction 174 54 Manufacturing 292 411 Transportation, Communications, and Utilities 83 55 <.nWho 1 esa 1 e Ret a i1 117 138 +'> Finance, Insurance 4e 4e and Real Estate Services l2e l3e Federal Government 678 707 State, Local Government 128 138 Total 1 1494 1526 e = estimated. TABLE 19. AVERAGE CIVILIAN MONTHLY EMPLOYMENT ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION, 1965-1978 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 137 125 142 195 285 187 181 422 471 349 476 657. 610 675 51 46 57 45 61 41 93 152 138 134 136 125 124 142 4e le 5 e· 7e 7e Be 7e lOBe 232e 268 143 240 82 47 633 550 523 528 574 640 704 157 160 174 168 178 206 227 1714 1835 1727 1721 2178 1982 2186 1974 180 851 93 137 12 33 813 257 2473 1Total includes minor amounts of mining and miscellaneous employment for some years. SOURCE: Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor) . .-- 1 ' l j 1975 1976 1977 1978 235 221 116 140 783 991 1130 1621 87 88 38 31 148 149 llOe lOle 27 32 37 38 .20 93 150 171 626 618 569 682 316 330 287 371 2349 2621 2474 3155 ,._.._....., . j available, there is steady growth indicated. Wholesale trade appears to be a much higher proportion of total wholesale-retail trade than is the case statewide, and this is apparently linked to wholesa1e trade activity associated w·ith fisheries. There may also be problems with the industrial classification of wholesale trade. Firms may engage in both buying or processing of fish and also wholesal- ing of fish or fish products. The firm's industrial classification would depend on which activity was of greater proportional significance, and this may change from year-to-year. The result is that the wholesale- retail sector reflects a strong mix of basic and support sector activity. In conjunction with possible industrial classification problems, this would account for the apparent lack of growth in this sector. There is one significant omission in the employment data; this is employment in commercial fishing·. Such employment is not included in the Statistical Q~arterly data, and as indicated above, a consistent series is not available elsewhere. Estimated commercial fishing em- ployment for 1978, however, was 756. If we include this figure with total reported employment of 3,155, the commercial fishing employment accounted for about 19 percent of total employment for 1978. Commer- cial fishing plus proces.sing employment amounts to 61 percent of total employment. A second issue of concern relates to the residency of job holders. Table 20 presents estimates of resident and nonresident employment for 55 TABLE 20. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION ESTIMATED RESIDENT AND NON-RESIDENT .. EMPLOYMENT, 1978 Industrx Resident Non-Resident Commercial Fishing 251 505 Manufacturing 162 1459 Construction 7 133 Transportation, Communication, and Uti 1 i ties 31 -0- Wholesale/Retail 89 12 Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate 38 -0- Services 171 -0- Federal Government Civilian, Military- Related -0-484 Other Federal Government 198 -0- State Government 88 -0- Local Government 283 -0- Total 1318 2593 e = estimated. Total 756 1621 140 31 lOle 38 171 484 198 88 283 3911 SOURCE: Commercial fishing; see text on production. Manufacturing total from Statistical Quarterly; see text on production for allocation. Federal government civilian military related; Table 18. All other data on tables from Statistical Quarterly (Alaska Department of Labor). For division of allocation to resident and nonresident, see text. 56 [ [ [ [ L [ [ [ [ [ . E [ f' L f' I L.o [ I 1978. The resident/nonresident breakdown for commercial fishing and· processing has already been explained. Allocation of the remainder of employment has been accomplished as follows: State and local government is assumed to be resident employment, as is also the case for transporta- tion, communications, and public utilities; finance, insurance, and real estate; and services. Federal government civilian employment was divided between defense-related and other Federal government activity. Defense- related employment was assigned to the nonresident category (in the sense that incomes earned had no impact on the A 1 euti an ·economy), while other Federal government employment was treated as resident employment. Retail trade was assumed to reflect resident employment. Wholesale trade includes both resident and nonresident employment, and one-half of the employment in wholesale was treated as resident. This division was based on discussions of wholesale trade activity in the AJeutians with the Alaska Department of Labor. The final industry of concern is contract construction. In conversations with several labor unions and contractors who operate in the Aleutians, it was clear that the vast majority of construction workers in the Aleutians are not residents of the area. Based on a synthesis of these conversations, it was estimated that 5 percent of contract construction employment in the Aleutians was accounted for by res.i dents. The remain- der was divided as follows: Anchorage (65 percent), southcentral Alaska (15 percent), the rest of the State (10 percent), and non-Alaska (10 per- cent). While this breakdown is necessarily an approximation, it does ~ 57 reflect the collective judgment of a .wide variety of participants .in contract construction in the Aleutians. Using the above delineation of employment between resident and nonresi- dent, it appears that just under 34 percent of the civilian employment in the Aleutians is held by residents. The remaining 66 percent is held by nonresidents. Available data do not permit us to estimate comparable breakdowns of employment for other years, and it is not possible to speculate on how the ratio of resident-to-nonresident employment may have changed over time. Summary data on labor force, unemployment, and employment for 1970-78 are presented in Table 21. It should be noted that the employment data in this tabl~ are not consistent with the data of the previous tables. First, the present table does not include estimates of commercial fishing employment. Second, the data reflect the number of job holders, whereas the previous tables reflect numbers of jobs. .The data are also supposed to be resident adjusted, although the resident employment estimate is substantially above that obtained in the previous table. Of particular interest are the data on unemployment and the unemployment rate. Given the seasonal variation in total activity, the rates are suprisingly low. This would suggest that several factors are at work. First, a high degree of seasonal migration is present. Second, Aleutian residents may tend to drop out of the labor force when employment oppor- tunities are not present~ Third, the data include a large proportion of government employment which tends to be seasonally stable. 58 .......... .:.~-•.---~ -. ~ ~--. ··----.··· ··--· -·--··' --·-·----··. --- r· [ r L [ [ [ [ 6 [ [ r· L I , I L --, _j -, - .,., """ """"' ~ ~ -~ -- ...l TABLE 21. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: CIVILIAN RESIDENT LABOR FORCE, TOTAL EMPLOYMENT, AND UNEMPLOYMENT 1970-1975 Unemployment Year Labor Force Employment Unemplo:t::ment Rate {%} 1970 1688 1575 113 6.7 1971 2041 1930 111 5.4 1972 1880 1763 . 117 6.2 1973 2109 1945 164 7.8 1974 1968 1830 138 7.0 1975 2371 2207 164 6.9 1976 2302 2147 155 6.7 1977 2102 1964 138 6.6 1978 2343 2196 147 6.3 SOURCE: Alaska Labor Force Estimates by Area (Alaska Department of Labor) various years. 59 A 1978 survey of potential labor force and employment of the Aleut popula- tion in the Aleutian region indicates that published data on unemployment may considerably understate the actual situation. Table 22 presents a. summary of the survey results. Of the potential labor of 575, only 278 were employed; only 222 earned $5,000 or more for that year; and 297 were not employed. This implies an unemployment rate of 51.7 percent. This probably over- states the "true" rate since only those of the potential labor force actually employed or seeking employment should be included in the labor force figures used to determine employment rates .. There is no way to tell what proportion of the potential labor force would actually seek employment if employment opportunities were available, but it appears that substanial real unemployment exists that is not reflected in pub- lished statistics. In summary, considerable growth in employment in the Aleutians has been evident. This has occurred mainly in response to growth of fisheries- related activity. This growth has also led to growth of employment in the support sector. While historical data are not available to indicate trends, nonresident employment accounts for a dominant proportion of total employment. It also appears that the Native Aleut population has not participated fully in the employment opportunities reflected by overall growth in total employment. Whether this is by choice or due to other reasons is not known. 60 r., L [ [ [ [ G [ [ I ·, L r. L [ ., ., -' J _J _j "" 3 -~ :j - ~ - TABLE 22. REPORT OF LABOR FORCE 1978 COMPILED BY BUREAU OF INDIAN AFFAIRS ANCHORAGE AGENCY Total Male a. Total Aleut population within the Aleutian region 2,139 1 '155 b. Total under 16 years of age included on line "a" 963 520 Resident Population of Working Age within the Aleutian Region c. Total 16 years and over (a minus b) l, 176 635 d. 16-24 years 447 241 e. 25-34 years 235 127 f. 35-44 years 212 114 g. 45-64 years 212 114 h. 65 years and over 70 38 i. Not in labor force (16 years and over) Total (j+k+l+m) 601 243 j. Students (16 years and over, including those away at school) 364 196 k. Men, physically or mentally disabled, retired, institu- · tionalized, etc. 47 47 1. Women for whom no child care substitutes are available 133 m. Women, housewives, physically or mentally disabled, insti- tutionalized, etc. 57 n. Potential labor force (16 years and over) (c minus i) 575 392 o. Employed, Total (p+q) 278 185 p. Employed, earning 5,000 or more a year (all jobs) 222 148 Employed, earning less than q. 5,000 a year (all jobs) 56 37 r. Not employed (n minus o) 297 207 SOURCE: Tribal Specific Health Plan (Aleutian-Pribilof Islands Association Health Department, undated). 61 Female 984 443 541 206 108 98 98 32 357 167 133 57 183 93 74 19 90 PERSONAL INCOME Personal income data for the Aleutian Census Division have-been compiled for the years 1965-1978 and are presented in Table 23. Growth in cur- rent dollar total personal income has been at a rate of about 7.4 percent per year, while per capita income has grown at about 7.2 percent per year. When measured in constant dollars, however, the growth has been substan- tially less. Real per capita income grew at 1.4 percent, while real total personal income grew at 1 .6 percent over the period. Several aspects of the data suggest that the numbers be interpreted with caution. First, the Anchorage Consumer Price Index was used to deflate the personal _income series since no more specific index is available. Hence, the adjustment is only approximate. Second, a large proportion of the income is related to military and-federal civilian employment directly linked to military activity. Since this income does not enter the Aleutian economy in any meaningful sense, its inclusion is mis- leading in terms of considering overall economic activity. Third, while the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) which compiles the data makes a resident adjustment, there is some question as to the validity of the adjustment. In particular, it is not clear to what extent the adjustment captures the effects of commerical fishing and processing incomes flowing out of the region. Finally, an analysis of transfer payments reported for the region shows sizable amounts related to federal military and related civilian employment that probably had no effect on the Aleutian economy. 62 ,~ L [ [ [ [ 6 r , L L ' _; ." _] ] - .J ' ·-_. ' ~ c-' TABLE 23. PERSONAL INCOME BY PLACE OF RESIDENCE: · ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION, 1965-1978 Current Dollars Constant (1978) Dollars Total Total (million $) Per Capita (million $) Per Capita 1965 33.951 4,721 70.207 9,763 1966 36.093 4,735 71.818 9,422 1967 38.886 4,727 75.750 9,208 1968 41.688 5,256 79.149 9,979 1969 43.677 5,484 79.296 9,956 1970 53.671 6,627 93.763 11,577 1971· 50.655 6,447 86.255 10,978 1972 49.968 6,580 83.267 10,965 1973 60.849 8,235 95.746 12,958 1974 66.084 8,280 91.949 ll ,520 1975 72.717 9,250 89.995 11,448 1976 81.383 9,837 94.592 11,434 1977 79.765 9,932 87.638 10,912 1978 85.734 11 ,619 85.734 11 ,619 SOURCE: Current dollar income figures from U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Constant dollar figures deflated by authors, using Anchorage Consumer Price Index. 63 For these and other reasons, we have attempted to develop an estimate of personal income for 1978 that more accurately reflects the sources and disposition of personal income for the region. These estimates are shown in Table 24. As shown in the table, we have indicated personal income sources by type, accruing from the broad industrial classifications designated at the top of the table. The left hand column of the table indicates the estimated breakdown of income to resident and nonresident recipients. Inclusion of the military and related civilian federal income as non- resident is a judgmental decision based on the fact that these incomes do not appear to enter the general income stream of the Aleutian econom~·, but rather reflect enclave activity. While much of the basis for allocating income has already been ·estab- lished in preceding sections of this study dealing with the Aleutians, . there are several points that need to be expanded. In general, data on wages and salary income were obtained from the Statistical Quarterly for appropriate years. The Bureau of Economic Analjsis data on ••other labor income 11 were apportioned to specific private sector industries on a proportional basis and then assigned to either resident or nonresident categories in proportion to resident/nonresident wage and salary incomes. Dividends, interest, and rent were allocated to residents and nonresi- dents on the basis of total wage and salary income. Total transfer payments were adjusted to assign military transfers (except for veterans' pensions) to the nonresident category. In addition, 10 percent of 64 r~ L r L [ [ [ [ h t L L [ L L ..., "=' d ' ..J .:; ~ TABLE 24. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS PERSONAL INCOME, 1978 BY PLACE OF WORK AND TO PLACE OF RESIDENCE Income ~ Support Contract Commercial Fish Fed. Gov. Fed. Gov. Sector Construction · Fishing Processing Civilian Military ENDOGENOUS HOUSEHOLDS: TOTAL ALLOCATED BY INDUSTRY Wages & Salaries 3.715 0.381 0 2.353 3.022 0 Other Labor Income 0.695 0.071 0 0.440 0 0 Proprietors' Income 0.951 0.098 12.250 0 0 0 UNALLOCATED COMPONENTS: Dividends·, Interest, and Rents Transfer Payments OUT OF REGION: Wages & Salaries /.nchorage 0 4.709 0 0 0 0 Southcentral 0 1.087 0 0 0 0 Rest of State 0 0.725 0 0 0 0 Rest of World 0.275 0.725 0 21.173 5.867 40.584 Other Labor Income Anchorage 0 0.881 0 0 0 0 Southcentra 1 0 0.203 0 0 0 0 Rest of State 0 0.136 0 0 0 0 Rest of World 0.051 0.136 0 3.958 0 0 Proprietors' Income Anchorage 0 0 0.780 0 0 0 Southcentra1 0 0 33.600 0 0 0 Rest of State 0 0 2.130 0 0 0 Rest of World 0 .Q 56.870 0 0 0 UNALLOCATED, OUT OF REGION: Dividends, Interest, and Rents Rest of World Transfers Rest of World TOTAL -5.687 9.152 105.630 27.924 8.889 "40.584 SOURCE: See text on personal income. 65 State & Local Govt. Total 5.206 14.677 0 1.206 0 13.299 0.317 3.501 0 4.709 0 1.087 0 0.725 0 68.624 0 0.881 0 0.203 0 0.136 0 4.145 0 0.780 0 33.600 0 2.130 0 56.870 1.623 4.813 5.206 213.326 ' '·' federal civilian retirement payments were assigned to residents~ with the remainder assigned to nonresidents. With the exception of these adjustments~ the remainder of transfer payments were assigned to residents. Proprietor's income is the income of self-employed and unincorporated enterprises. A large portion of this component for the Aleutians should ·!\reflect commercial fishing income~ and it was felt that BEA figures did not adequately reflect this income. An estimate of noncommercial fish- ing proprietor's income \-Jas made by assuming that the proportion of proprietor 1 S income to wage and salary plus other labor income was the same for the State as for the Aleutians. This led to an estimate of noncommercial fishing proprietor's income of 4.1 million dollars. Proprietor's income from commercial fishing was based on the value of catch. No reliable data exist on net profits from commercial fishing. It has been estimated~ however~ that about 35 to 40 percent of the value of catch is reflected in labor income (Scott~ Prospects for a-Bottom- fishing Industry in Alaska); hence, 35 percent of the value of catch has been used to estimate proprietor's income. This figure has been used in conjunction with the estimated 1978 southwest region value of catch to estimate proprietor's income~ as shown in the table~ and was allocated by factors established in Table 17. In general~ the data for 1978 show total personal income of 213.3 million. Of this total, residents who are part of the nonenclave economy of the region accrued 33 million dollars. Of the 180 million dollars accruing 66 l' r I L F [ -t_: [ r, L r~ I L. r· to nonresidents, about 46.5 million dollars represent wage and salary payments to military personnel and related federal civilian employees, with the remainder (133.9 million dollars) going to other nonresidents. In terms of the regional allocation of the 180 million dollars, about 6.4 million dollars flowed to the Anchorage region; while 34.9 million dollars went to the southcentral region (primarily Kodiak), with an additional 3.0 million dollars going to the rest of the State. About 136.1 million dollars primarily from commercial fishing and defense- related activities appeared to flow outside the State. Thus, while total personal income was substantial, over 84 percent of the income created by production in the Aleutians flowed out of the Aleutian regio.1. These are indeed very high leakages and present a different picture of the Aleutian economy than that indicated by the BEA personal income data. In addition to the analysis of total and per capita income, it is again appropriate to consider the distribution of income. Recent data on income distribution are not available, but the Bureau of Indian Affairs prepared an estimate of the 1974. distribution of income which is pre- sented in Table 25. The distribution is shown for both Native and white families. Median income for the two groups is similar, and both are well below the statewide figure of 12,443 dollars for the same year. The greatest disparity between Native and white families appears in the under-5,000 dollar groups, with 26 percent of the Native families and 13.8 percent of white families with incomes below 5,000 dollars. It should be noted that the non-Native families include military personnel, 67 TABLE 25. FAMILY INCOME: NUMBER AND PERCENT OF NATIVE AND WHITE FAMILIES BY INCOME LEVELS _ ALEUT CORPORATION AREA Native White No. of Families Percent No. of Families Under_ J ,000 7 2.1 0 1 ,ooo.:.1 ,99~11 16 4.9 6 2,000-2,999 ' 13 4.0 7 3,000-3,999 30 9.2 31 4,000-4,999 19 5.8 45 5,000-5,999 20 6.1 55 6,000-6,999 26 8.0 65 7,000-7,999 25 7.7 63 8,000-8,999 21 6.4 72 9,000-9,999 18 5.5 37 10,000-11 ,999 40 12.2 88 12~000-14,999 31 9.5 102 15,000-24,999 56 17.1 43 25,000-49,999 5 1.5 17 50,000 0 0 Median Income $8,357 $8,604 Percent 0 1.0 1.1 4.9 7.1 8.7 10.3 10.0 11.4 5.9 13.9 16.2 6.8 2.7 0 [ [ [ [ F F SOURCE: Tribal Specific Health Plan (Aleutian-Pribilof Islands Association-1_- Health Department, undated). l r -, L r - 68 L [ _, j whose incomes tend to flatten the distribution somewhat; whereas for the Native distribution, the under-5,000 dollar and over~l5,000 dollar income categories are proportionately more important. POPULATION Aggregate population data for 1960 and the years 1970-78 are presented in Table 26; it includes total resident and civilian population and military population. Considerable variation in the military p~pulation is evident; although for most of the period, it averaged a little over 3,000. ·For recent years, it has been somewhat lower, dropping to 1,655 in 1978. Total civilian population has shown a steady increase, attribu- table to both natural increase and net in-migration. Table 27 shows the component of change in both civilian and military population over the 1~70-78 period. Civilian population has grown at about 4.8 percent, with natural increase accounting for 47 percent of the total increase. The remainder is accounted for by net in-migration. Table 28 provides data on population by community and by Native and non- Native components. The data totals are not in strict agreement with the other population data presented but do provide a generally accurate pic- ture of the population distribution in the census division, with major nongovernment-based communities at King Cove, Sand Point, St. Paul, and Unalaska. It is no coincidence that (with the exception of St. Paul) these are the major centers of commercial fishing activity in the Aleutians. 69 TABLE 26. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CIVILIAN AND TOTAL RESIDENT POPULATION: 1960, 1970-1978 Total Resident Total Civilian . Population Population Military 1960 . 6,011 2,633 3,378 1970 8,057 4,368 3,689 1971 ··7,896 I 4,285 3,611 1972 7 ,245 1 4,634 2,611 1973 6,914 3,994 2,920 1974 7,714 4,506 3,208 1975 7,086 4,208 2,878 1976 8,282 5,300 2,982 1977 7,686 4,896 2,790 1978 8,000 6,345 1,655 SOURCE: Alaska Department of Labor I' l- f- L [ E [ [ ~ [ [ 1- L [ TABLE 27. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS: COMPONENTS OF POPULATION CHANGE, 1970-78 1970 Population Births Deaths Natural Increase Net Migration Ci vi 1 ian Military 1978 Population SOURCE: Alaska Department of Labor 71 8,057 1,106 176 930 1,047 -2,034 8,000 Akutan Atka Bel kofski False Pass King Cove 1 Nelson Lagoon Nikolski 1 Sand Point St. George St. Paul Unalaska Other Total TABLE 28. ALEUT REGION POPULATION BY COMMUNITY, 1977 Native Non-Native Total 69 5 74 92 3 95 14 14 55· \f\ 57 425 142 567 49 6 55 56 2 58 490 339 829 175 9 184 437 63 500 168 557 725 126 5,7002 5,826 2,156 6,828 8,984 1city Manager's figures.· 2Includes military population. Transient 360 -800 120 60 65 700 -3,(;00 1,305-4,045 SOURCE: Tribal Specific Health Plan (Aleutian-Pribilof Islands IJ.c:snr;a+;on uea 1 +h D"''"'a""tm"~+ .. ~...~~t"d' ,,...,. '""""·"'' WI II II-I \..II ..::;p I I ~lit..., UliUQ t:: J o 72 I' I f .. l ; l I /_ r l [ r· l . .i I L r I L L III. THE BASE CASE In this part of the report we deal with three critical elements of the base case. The first of these is the underlying methodology used to develop the base case. The second element concerns the assumption re- garding the future economic activity used to develop the projections. The third is the set of projections themselves. Impact analysis, as carried out in the present study, is based upon a comparison of sets of economic and demographic projections, where one set is the standard or base case set. The base case serves as a frame of reference against which the economic and demographic changes re- sulting from the proposed OCS lease sale can be measured and evaluated. There are two components of this process that are of particular concern. First the question of the accuracy and consistency of the projections. Generally speaking, this is dependent upon the validity of the assumptions utilized regarding future economic growth of the exogenous variables and the projection methodology employed. More will be said on both of these points below. The second concern relates to the degree of information contained in the projections. Specifically, do the projections contain the information that is necessary to adequately interpret and evaluate the impacts? 73 ---..... -· ... --... -..:..-..... -_..,_ ~--· ~-.. --.... ~,--,. ~-~---··. --~-~------... --.. --~··-.-----------·p····-.... --.. -----·····- While aggregate data on economic and demographic variables generated _using the projections methodology employed in this study will answer many questions, it must be recognized that there will be omissions as well. At the root of impact analysis is the issue of. how economic well-being, ·I\ both individually and collectively, will be affected by the proposed action. Two major problems are associated with this process. First it is not possible to measure all impacts that will result from the lease sale. In part this is due to the volume of information that would be required and the inadequacy of the existing methodology to capture all effects at an acceptable level of cost. The more serious problem is that many of-the effects are not measurable. While reallocation of resources within the context of the functioning of the market, in response to economic change, is desirable from the perspective of efficiency, change on the order of magnitude implied by OCS activity may also lead to situations of market failure and the presence of externalities. These are often difficult to identify and are certainly difficult to measure. Even if these effects could be isolated they are usually inseparable from a further problem, that of income redistribution. Changes in income distribution and the relative economic position of individuals resulting from OCS activity necessarily implies that there will be lossers and gainers and associated changes in economic welfare. These are problems that involve normative economic judgements and cannot be 74 ~ L - [ [ ,. L [ [ [ L t [ I. L L __ ;i dealt with by impact analysis alone. In short, comparative impact analysis provides only part o.f the information necessa.ry for decision making. We can now turn to a discussion of the specific methodology employed in developing the present base case projections (and associated OCS impacts projections). At the statewide and regional level two models have been utilized, the MAP statewide econometric model and the MAP regional econometric model. For documentation see Goldsmith, Man-in-the-Arctic Program: Alaska Economic Model Documentation. The MAP statewide model is actually a system of models composed of economic, fiscal, and popu- lation models. The three are interdependent, as shown schematically in Figure 2. FIGURE 2· MAP Sub-Models Economic Model - Population Fiscal .. Model Model 75 ' ,. In essence, this states that the economic model receives in~ut from the fiscal and population models, the fiscal model receives input from the economic and population models, and the population model utilizes input from the economic models, but not directly from the fiscal model. Thus, when we talk about the economic model we are really describing the interaction of three models. To simplify things somewhat we 'can\?rscribe the important linkages between submodels and then consider the economic model in more detail. The population-economic model link is the source of population estimates that are of direct interest, and reflect both natural population change and migration induced by changes in economic conditions. The population estimates are also used by the economic model for purposes of computing various per capita values for economic variables. The significant link with the fiscal model relates to the role of State government expenditures as a source of major economic stimulus to the aggregate level of economic activity. In turn, State government (and local government) expenditures are dependent upon two key factors, the overall level of economic activity and the level of activity in the petroleum industry. The system allows for a variety of policy choices regarding state government spending and is one of the key points to con- sider in assessing economic forecasts. 76 L [ - [ [ [ f ' L I I L [ We can now turn to a consideration of the economic model component of the system. The MAP statewide and regional models belong to a class of econometric models that are known as disaggregate economic base models. In essence~ economic activity is classified as either endogenous or exogenous (or basic). Exogenous activity determines the level of endogenous activity, and the specific relationships between the two components of economic activity are what make up the system of equations that are the econo- metric model. These models can be quite simple or rather complex, and the MAP models fall in this latter category. It is possible to get a feel for the models by considering the MAP statewide model. As can be seen in Figure 3, determination of industrial production involves the impact of exogenous sector activity, which includes for- estry, fisheries, agriculture and other manufacturing, as well as Federal government wages and salaries. Other exogenous sector activity includes the petroleum industry and components of contract construction such as major pipelines. State and local government expenditures may also be considered as exogenous for discussion purposes, although there is some interdependence between these expenditures and total economic activity. It should be noted that in constructing scenarios for forecasting or projection purposes it is primarily these exogenous variables that must be provided. 77 r -FIGURE 3. MAP STATEWIDE MODEL [ L [ [ Stole and ,• Local +---+ Petroleum Government 'I\ r·· l ... EXOGENOUS SECTORS SUPPORT SECTOR Forestry I Construction J-Trade Fislleries Finance Federal government Services Agriculture Transportation Other manufacturing Communications Public utilities I ' ' -i Industrial Production L._ I I ~ l- r- L I' f, L_ Employment ! I Wage I Wages and Rates I Salaries [ ! L I Non wage L .... Personal Income I Income ~-_[ I Personal I Disposable Taxes I Personal Income ~ f' I Consumer l Real Disposable Prices I Personal Income-[j L L f ' L SOURCE: Man-In-The-Arctic Program Alaskan Economic Model Documentation (ISER~ 1979). 78 r· I L [ These exogenous variables combine with demand from the support sector and endogenous construction to generate total industrial production. Industrial production, through a series of steps, determines employment and income, and finally real disposable personal income, which in turn is a determinant of support sector and endogenous construction economic ·activity. This means that aggregate production depends· on both exoge- nously determined and endogenously determined economic activity, where endogenous activity depends on total activity. As such, the system is a simultaneous equation structure. It should also be noted that certain other variables enter the model as well. In particular, wage rates are used in determining total wage and salary payments, where the wage rates are in part dependent upon U.S. wage rates, which are determined exogenously. It should also be observed that the model is particularly sensitive to the wage rates used. The MAP regional model is structurally similar to the statewide model except that the model is disaggregated to seven regions. (See Figure 4) This means that scenarios (or future values for exogenous variables) . must be specified on a regional basis and that forecasts of endogenous variables (such as income, employment, and population) will be generated on a regional basis. Otherwise the models are similar. For the Aleutian Islands Census Division projections have been developed. using the small community population impact model (SCIMP). For documentation 79 ~ .............. . ~ ......................... . r---, '· . "' 2 SouthyJest . 1 . · North. Slope ~ L . ; 7 Fairbanks. MAP REGIONS FIGURE 4. . . --.1..-.,.,outhcentra 1 . 7 ~ . Southeast C\ ~ " ---.,.v (~~~··~ . ~ . ~~~~· 3,.• ..... : . ~ ·. u·~ . . . •• . ~ ~r',i ~' J \' '\;:: /"'!, .. 'h'\•. . ....~~~\..~\~ i \\I, · \ .l~· -..~"<s,\..J 'I ···' ·' " .. ,,~ .~· ·.~. ' '.'-'1:0 . . •• t~··~·· Southwest (part) .\ .~ . ': . • ' ! o I ·.dJ~ ., I ~ 0 l Q 5:7/.lw--.... ,t> • ~ • j see Lee Huskey and Jim Kerr, 11 Smal1 Community Population Impact Model 11 • Whereas the ~1AP models are classified as econometric models SCIMP is technically an accounting model. A system of equations describes the economic and demographic structure of the economic system. In turn parameters of the equations and a set of exogenous variable inputs provide the numerical basis for utilizing the·model for projection purposes. It is the determination of parameters for the model that distinguishes SCIMP from econometric models. In an econometric model, parameters are typically determined by the application of econometric methods to historical time series or cross section data and the parameter estimates are an integral component. of the model. In the case of SCIMP the parameters are determined exog- enously by a variety of means, including point estimates, assumptions based on other research, and in some instances by econometric estimation techniques. In other words, in SCIMP both the parameters and exogenous variable data are .inputs, while in an econometric model the parameter estimates are an integral part of the model. There are both advantages and shortcomings to this approach. On the positive side, SCIMP is generally applicable to small regional economies, rather than being region specific, as would be the case with an econo- metric model. This results in substantially more limited data require- ments than is the case for a fully estimated econometric model. The 81 ' I· shortcoming is also indicated by the less stringent data requirements. Specifically, the quality of the parameter estimates may not be as great as that obtained by econometric techniques. However, the costs ·are substantially less. We can now turn to a discussion of the assumptions utilized in developing the base case projections. Since distinct sets of assumptions are necessary for each of the models, these will be considered in turn. 82 r· L [ [ L [ E L [ f. L L Non-OCS Base Case Assumptions: MAP Models NATIONAL VARIABLES ASSUMPTIONS Inasmuch as Alaska is an open economy, it is affected by changes in the national economy. Consequently, several assumptions about the future growth of the U.S. economy are required. The assumptions needed are threefold. First, a forecast of average weekly earnings in the United States is required as an input into the estimation of Alaskan wage rates. Second, the Alaskan price level is tied in part to the national price level so that a forecast of the U.S. consumer price index is needed. Finally, inasmuch as a major determinant of migration to Alaska is the income differential between Alaska and the lower 48, a forecast is required of real per capital disposable income in the United States. The long-run assumptions for these national variables are based on long- term forecasts prepared by Data Resources, Inc., in their September 1979 forecast of U.S. economic activity (TRENDLONG0979). This forecast pre- dicts a long-run average rate of increase in the U.S. consumer price index of 8.85 percent through 1990. A rate of 8.3 percent (the 1990 value) is used for the 1991-2000 period. Real disposable per capita income is forecast to increase at a 3.38 percent average annual rate. Hourly earnings are forecast to increase at 10.2 percent, while average hours worked are forecast to decline slowly at -0.23 percent. 83 The Base Case Assumptions ·' The impact of OCS development on the economy will be measured as the change from the level of activity from the base case. The base case is defined as the level of activity which is projected to occur without the OCS lease sale of interest. This section describes the base case which will be used in this study. A set of assumptions about the future level of various exogenous econo- mic activity defines a development scenario. A development scenario is required to forecast the future level of activity in the economy with each model used in the analysis. There are three major types of assump- tions required for a development scenario. First, the models require assumptions about the future level of national variables which directly or indirectly affect Alaska economic activity. Secondly, assumptions about the future development of the exogenous sectors of the Alaska economy are required. These assumptions can be separated into OCS and non-OCS assumptions; the major difference between the base case and the impact case is the addition to the OCS assumptions of the OCS lease sale of interest. Finally, the models require assumptions about the State government finances. These include both assumptions about State expend- iture decisions and assumptions about the level of exogenous State revenues. 84 [ L [ L L F r- ' L ... --~----·. [ Consequently, average weekly earnings may be expected to grow at an annual rate of 9.97 percent (i.e., 10.2 percent minus 0.23 percent). These long-term average growth rates were adopted as the three national variable assumptions utilized in the analysis. THE ECONOMIC SCENARIOS The economic scenarios consist of time series on employment and output in certain export base or exogenous industries. This does not mean that we are predicting that all or any of these events will occur since there is a highly variable degree of uncertainty with respect to the levels and timing of the events in these scenarios. What it does mean is that with a certain degree of probability, we expect the general level of economic activity to follow this scenario. We assume that there is a medium probability that the level of activity will be at least as great as that described by this scenario. The major exception to this important assumption is related to the exogenous series in fisheries-related activity. These series were developed by Sea Grant and Earl Coombs, Inc., under contract with the BLM/ Alaska OCS Office. The components related to bottomfishing, in the opinion of the ISER staff, are greatly in excess of what can reasonably be expected to actually occur. To the extent that these series do in fact turn out to be too high, then the aggregate projections will also be high and the probability that they will be achieved must necessarily be reduced. Since we have been specifically instructed to use the series by the Alaska OCS Office we have done so, but we are not in agreement with the assumptions. 85 Primarily as a result of the uncertainty attached to the occurrence, magnitude, and timing of any particular event, agreement about partie- ular scenarios is hard to achieve even among those most knowledgeable about the Alaska economy. Emphasizing our concern mainly with general levels of activity, the probabilistic nature of the specific scenario should reduce the disagreement. In an attempt to reduce even further the disagreement, the scenario was developed based upon existing scenar- ios which have attained same measure of consensus. The most important source for these scenarios were the scenarios developed in the level B Southcentral ~Jater Study (Scott, 1979) and the Susitna Dam feasibility study (Goldsmith and Huskey, 1980). The major exception is the series related to bottomfishing activity, as commented upon above. The economic scenario is described in Table 29. The assumptions are described below; these discussions are organized by industry. Mining Currently, the mining sector in Alaska is dominated both in employment and output by the petroleum industry. This is assumed to continue in the future. The scenario includes production at P.rudhoe Bay and in the Upper Cook Inlet. Production from the Sadlerochet formation at Prudhoe is assumed to include both primary recovery and secondary recovery using water flooding. Development of the water flooding facilities begins in 1982. 86 r I L L [ [ L [ L f L L The Kuparak formation is also assumed to be developed with production rising to 120,000 barrels per day by 1984. Employment assoCiated with these developments peaks in the early 1980s with the development of Kuparak and the water flooding project .. Upper Cook Inlet employment is assumed to remain at its existing level throughout the projection period. This assumes a rising level of exploration, development, and production of gas in the Kenai fields which would replace employment lost because of declining oil production. Also included is exploration, development, and production in NPRA, beginning in 1985. Finally, the mining inc 1 udes the "moderate.. cases of the fo 11 owing OCS leases: Beaufort State/Federal Sale, Northern Gulf (Sale 55), the two Cook Inlet Sales, and the Bering-Norton Sale (57). 87 co co Special !Projects Trans-Alaska Pipeline Northwest Gasline Prudhoe Bay Petroleum Production Upper Cook Inlet Petroleum Pro- duction r--- l ,.._..._ L . TABLE 29. SCENARIO ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS Description The construction of the TAPS was com- pleted in 1977. · Additional construc- tion of four pump stations is assumed as well as pipeline operations. Construction of natural. gas pipeline from Prudhoe Bay which in~ eludes construction of an associated gas conditioning facility on the North Slope. Primary recovery from Sadlerochit formation, secondary recovery using water flooding of that formation and development of the Kuparuk formation. Employment associated with declining oil production is assumed to be replaced by employment associated with rising gas pro- duction maintaining current levels of employment. Dates & Employment 1979-1982 -Pump station construction of 90/year 1977-2000 -Operations employment of 1500/yr. 1982-1986 -Construc- tion peak employment of 7,823 (1984) 1986-2000 -Operations begin employing 400 petroleum and 200 transport workers Location Operations employ- ment allocated: 1/3 to Southcentral 1/3 to Fairbanks l/3 to N. Slope Source E. Porter, Bering-Norton Statewide-Regional Economic and Demographic Systems, Impact Analysis, Alaska OCS Socioeconomic Studies Program, Bureau of Land Management, 1980. 2/3 of pipeline E. Porter, 1980. construction and transportation employment in Fair- banks. 1/3 in North Slope. All gas conditioning employemnt in North Slope. 1982-1984 -Construction All in North Slope E. Porter, 1980. of water flooding pro- ject peak employment of 2,917 (1983) 1980-2000 -Mining employ- ment long-run average of 1,802/year · 1980-2000 -Mining em-All in Southcental E. Porter, 1980 ployment of 705/year region ,____..., . I l .:J L. . J Special Projects Beluga Coal Pro- duct ion Pacific LNG Project Petrochemical Development 00 ~ Sus itna Project National Petroleum Reserve in Alaska Bradley Lake l. i J •.. J l . J [ I J .J TABLE 29. SCENARIO ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS (cont.) Descri~tion Dates & Em~lo~ment Location Moderate development 1985-1990-construe-Located in of Beluga coal re-tion -peak employment Southcental source for export. of 400 ( 1987) region 1988-2000 -operations· employment of 210/year long-run average Construction of cur-1982-1985 -Construe-Located in rent proposal by tion peak employment Southcentral Pacific LNG of 1,323/year (1984) region 1986-2000 -Operations employment of 100/yr. Development includes · 1984-1986 -construe-Southcentral refinery and petro-tion employment of chemical facility 2400/year using states royalty 1987-2000 -operations has as feed stock. employment 1118/year Construction of two 1984-1998-construe-Southcentral dams on the Susitna tion peak employment River for a major 1414 (1992). hydroelectric project. 1991-2000 -operations employment 19 per dam. Petroleum production Leases held between in NPRA. Production 1983-1990. Develop- in five fields with a ment and exploration total reserve of 2.5 begins in 1985. billion bbls equiva-Average mining employ- lents of oil and gas. ment of 460/year. Construction of 525 miles of pipeline. Construction of hydro-1981-1985 -construe-. Southcentra 1 electric facility tion -peak employment of 300 (1983) 1986-2000 -Operations employment (10) Source Pacific Northwest Labora- tory, Beluga Coal Field Development: Social Effects and Management Alternatives, 1979. ·E. Porter, 1980. Based on modifed Alpetco proposal (E. Porter, 1980) and J. Kruse, Fairbanks Petrochemical Study, 1978. E. Porter, 1980. Based on mean scenario under Management Plan 2 in Office of Minerals Policy and Research Analysis, U.S. Department of Interior, Final Report of the l05(b) Economic and Policy Analysis, 1979. Industry Assumptions Fisheries/Food Process ·i ng Forestry/Pulp and Paper Manufacturing ~ Other Manu- facturing Federal Govern- ment Other Mining Agriculture r--- l ·' TABLE 29. SCENARIO ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS (cont.) Description Small increase in em- ployment in tradi- tiona 1 fishery. t4ajor expansion of domestic groundfish industry. Expansion to replace foreign fishery in the 200 mile limit by 2000. Employment expands to accommodate 960 mil- lion board feet of 1 umber. Expansion of existing manufacturing of locally consumed goods. Civilian employment assumed to grow at recent historical rate. Military declines at 0.05% No expansion of exist- ing nonspecial pro- jects. Assumes that a rela- tively low priority is given to agriculture development because of priorities for recreation and wilder- ness or the lack of markets. ,...,.......... l ... 1.: ) Dates & Employment Fishery employment ex- pands to 9638 by 2000 (resident). Processing employment expands to 10,420 by 2000 (resident}. Growth of output at 4% per year. Civil ian emp'loyment grows at 1.0%/year Railbelt Location Source ~~----------------- Resident regional Sea Grant, 1980; Earl Coombs, employment in year Inc., memo to OCS; OCS. 2000: F P Southcentral 2658/2405 Southeast 1376/538 Northwest 57/17 Southwest 5547/7306 Anchorage 0/154 Approximately 11% M. Scott, 1979. of activity in Fairbanks region. Remainder in South- east. Regional distribu- tion based on ex- isting distribution of employment. Existing regional distribution. M. Scott, 1979. Employment constant at Regional allocation 1979 level, 2,350/yr. constant Employment grows to 1 ' 03 7 by 2000. ,.---...... I I . . ) 71% of growth M. Scott, 1979. located in Fairbanks region and 29% in South- central region. Other regions re- main the same. _j In addition to the petroleum development, some other mining is assumed to take place. Development of the Beluga coal resources is assumed. In this scenario, coal is assumed to be produced for export. The special projects described above do not exhaust the mining employ- ment in the state. Additional employment occurs in the exploration, development, and production of nonpetroleum minerals, a~ well as a major component of headquarters employment in Anchorage. Market forcei and governmental policies are assumed to be such that this component of mining remains constant. Agriculture-Forestry-Fisheries This industry is, in reality, three distinct subindustries which re- present Alaska•s renewable resource industries. Of the three, the fishing industry is currently the largest in terms of both employment and value of product. Agriculture is currently only a marginal industry employing few people statewide (Scott, 1979). Current state efforts to develop agriculture may lead to its increased importance in the future. Forestry consists of only a small component; the future of forestry is most appropriately discussed with the future of lumber and wood products manufacturing. The future of agricultural development in the state depends importantly on governmental policies and actions. State and Federal land policies, infrastructut·e development and loan programs, and marketing programs will determine the future of this industry. Agriculture is assumed to 91 rise only slightly from its current levels of employment. This assumes that agriculture receives low priorities from government. Fisheries also hold promise for the future. The major determinant of future increases in fisheries employment will be the expansion of the Alaska bottomfish industry. The creation of the 200 mile limit may support increased Alaska bottomfish activity~ The fishing industry is assumed to undergo a rapid expansion in this scenario. Total resident employment in fisheries grows at 8.0 percent per year over the projection period, while employment in processing expands at 13.3 percent. This growth results primarily from the develop- ment of the bottomfish industry. The domestic fishery is assumed to completely replace the foreign fishery operating within the 200 mile 1 imit by 2000 and expand to catch the allowable biological catch (Sea Grant, 1980; Earl Coombs, Inc. memo to BLM/AK OCS Office, and BLM/AK OCS Office). We would state again that we feel that the bottomfish projections are substantially over optimistic and we are using them at the instruction of the BLM/AK OCS Office. Not all fishery related employment is assumed to have full economic impact on the state and regional economy. Boats and crews may be from outside and only fish Alaska waters; these crews have limited impact on the economy. Processing employees are also often brought in from outside the state and live in enclaves having little effect. For this reason, the resident share rather than total employment has been used. Table 30 provides estimates for 1980, 1990, and 2000. 92 f~ l L~ [ L [ L r-~ ~ ' [ [ r, L I L L ~~ " lj l •I I I I J ' ..... " I~J" ' .J ,_, "', ,,1 1,,,, '''"'" ' ' ) I' _I •' 1 ij ' ',j L , , .J J J .J TABLE 30 RESIDENT EMPLOYMENT IN FISHERIES Harvesting Rest of the Year Aleutians Southwest North\'Ves :t Southeast Southcentral Anchorage Total 1980 388 642 ' 57 1259 1164 0 3510 1990 1141 642 57 1301 130'3 0 4444 2000 4905 642 57 1376 2658 0 9638 Processing Rest of the Year Aleutians Southwest Northwest Southeast Southcentral Anchorage Total 1.0 w 1980 175 32 21 225 359 39 851 1990 1394 65 21 420 503 53 2456 2000 7208 98 17 538 2405 154 10420' SOURCE: See text. For the Aleutians and part of Southcentral (Kodiak) the figures were supplied by OCS, for bottomfishing. The remainder of traditional and bottomfishing total employment projections, by region, were obtained from Sea Grant (1980). Residency adjustments were developed utilizing residency factors in Rogers (1980) and are based upon residence of fishermen, by type of gear, fishing in each of the regions. Projections for processing were similarly developed. Federal Government Federal government employmen~ has always been an important component of Alaska 1 s economy. In recent years, Federal government employment has been growing very little; increases in civilian employment have been offset by decreases in military employment. Low rates of growth in Federal government employment are assumed to occur. Civilian employment grows at about l percent per year, while military employment declines at 0.05 percent per year. Manufacturing The manufacturing industry_in Alaska has four important components: seafood processing, lumber-wood products-pulp, petrochemicals, and manu- facturing for the local economy. Production of seafood processing is expected to continue to dominate the food processing industry in Alaska; growth of this industry was based on projections provided by Sea Grant to SESP (Sea Grant, 1980 and OCS, as explained above). The growth of the lumber-wood-paper-pulp sector of manufacturing in the state is determined primarily by two factors. These are the Forest 94 r· I l .. [~ r ~ ~ [ L [ L r I L_ L Service allowable annual cut and the Japanese,market conditions. Growth in lumber-wood-paper-pulp reflect an increase in annual allowed cut by half the 1970 Jevel over the period. The petrochemical industry in Alaska currently consists of the develop- ments in Kenai. The petrochemical industry expands with the construe- tion of the Pacific LNG facility as currently planned and the development of a petrochemical facility which uses the state 1 s royalty oil and gas. The petrochemical complex is assumed to use the state 1 s royalty gas, to produce ethylene or fuel-grade methanol, as well as include a fuels refinery as defined by Alpetco. Although no major proposal like this is currently proposed, interest in such a project has currently been expressed by major international .firms. The final component of the manufacturing industry consists of those industries producing for local consumption and other diverse specialized production. It was assumed that this sector would grow because of increased market size, allowing scale economies which make local pro- duction viable. This sector was assumed to grow at 4 percent per year. Transportation . The exogenous portion of the transportation industry is that which serves special projects. This industry includes the operations employ- ment for TAPS and the Northwest gasline. 95 Construction The final exogenous industry for which scenarios are required is that portion of the construction industry where the level is determined outside the economy. This sector includes construction employment associated with the special projects described above. This sector does not include capital improvement projects of any level of government or construction activity which supports the local economy; the remainder of construction activity is determined endogenously in the MAP model. The major development of special projects occurs in the early part of the projection period. The most important project during this period is the construction of the Northwest gasline which is assumed to begin in 1982. The construction of the petrochemical facility is assumed to begin in 1984. An additional major construction project is the construction of the Susitna Hydro Project which begins in 1984. Construction of the bottomfish processing facilities projected also increase employment. It is assumed that it will require 40 man years to build a processing plant (conversation with industry sources). STATE FISCAL POLICY ASSUMPTIONS Past studies of the Alaskan economy conducted within the Man-in-the- Arctic Program, the OCS Studies Program~ and other miscellaneous pro- grams have indicated repeatedly the key role of State government fiscal policy as a major determinant of both historical and future State economic growth. Over the period of study, State government will receive revenues from oil development which far exceed current levels of expenditure. The 96 r~ I \!__. I L: [ I' L [ [ . r·' L r, ' L [ rate at which the government chooses to-spend these revenue~ (or to offset existing revenue sources with them) will serve to determine not only direct employment in the government sector but, through the multi- plier effects of such expenditures or tax reductions, will have impacts on all endogenous sectors, affecting the growth of employment, income, prices, and migration into the state. Two factors affect the current framework in which State fiscal policy will be determined. First, revenues have already overtaken expenditures as a consequence of .the onset of production from Prudhoe Bay and will continue to increase as a consequence of both increased production and I price increases. Second, the establishment of the Permanent Fund, as a constitutional amendment in 1976, places constraints on the use of certain petroleum revenues. It requires that a minimum of 25 p~rcent of all mineral lease rentals, royalties., royalty sale proceeds, Federal - mineral revenue sharing payments, and bonuses received by the State be put in the fund. These changes in the structure of State spending limit the usefulness of past fiscal policies in determining the fiscal policy rules to be used. The rate of State expenditures, because it is a matter of policy choice within this new framework, cannot be modeled simply from past experience. Past experience can,. however, provide qualitative guidance in formulating hypothetical fiscal policy options for use in simulation. First, we can expect that, as in the past, increasing levels of economic activity 97 generate new demands for government services. As prices and population rise, increased expenditure is required to simply maintain services at a constant level. In fact, however, this level will be expected to rise over time if historical trends continue. Secondly, historical data gives at least some indication of State fiscal policy response to surplus petroleum revenues. The revenues generated by the Prudhoe Bay lease sale in FY 1970 led to a rapid jump in both the level and growth .of nominal and per capita expenditures, with nominal expenditures jumping from an average growth of 8.9 percent annually prior to the sale to an average 19.7 percent after the sale; and real per capita expenditures jumped from 2.3 percent prior to the sale to 7.7 percent after the sale. If these qualitative features carry over into future fiscal responses to surplus petroleum revenues, future real per capita expenditures can be expected to rise within the bounds set by revenue quantities and statutory constraints. At a minimum, the State might choose simply to maintain real per capita expenditures at their current levels. At a maximum, it could choose to spend all but 25 percent of restricted petroleum rev~­ nues as they are incurred. Unfortunately, the range of possibilities within these brackets is very large. While it is foolish to try to anticipate the actual fiscal policy choices of the State, it is possible to simulate each of the extremes. As a compromise, for purposes of simulation, a middle-range policy can then be selected. strategy followed here. 98 This is the r~ I . [' l , ! . ,~ L I I_ [ [ ·r· ~ L f L~ I, I l_ The mid-range forecast used in the base case was developed as follows. First, exogenous petroleum revenues were estimated. The petroleum revenues used in this forecast were based on the most recent Petroleum Production Revenues Forecast which is prepared quarterly by the Alaska Department of Revenue. Next, two forecasts were made, one in which real per capita State government expenditures are maintained at existing levels and a second in which only the legislated minimum is saved. These cases provide the extremes. A path of growth in State expenditures which is midway between these extremes was chosen to use in the base case. The result was a growth rate of 14 percent in nominal State government expenditures. 99 Non-OCS Base Case Assumptions: SCIMP The utilization of SCIMP requires projection of a set of exogenous variables and a set of control parameters. In general the control parameters for the base case include: demographic parameters, labor force participation rates, and economic base multipliers. Parameters for the population distributions were based on 1970 census data and the Aleutian-Pribilof Islands Association Health Department, Tribal Specific Health Plan. Since we were concerned with the nonmili- tary and military dependents population, this component of total popu- lation was netted out for distribution purposes. Military and dependents are included in population totals however. Birth rates and survivor rate parameters were based on the 1970 census and more recent data or vital statistics from the U.S. Department of Health and Welfare. No noneconomic induced migration was assumed. Labor force participation rates by Cohort for residents 1t1ere based on 1970 census data and adjusted to current levels by reference to aggregate labor force participation rates indicated in Alaska Department of Labor data on work force and population. Data from the Tribal Specific Health Plan cited above were also utilized in establishing Native labor force participation rates. The multipliers needed were estimated from employment data for the Aleutians developed in Part II of the report. An aggregate multiplier, 100 [ [ I L r L [ [ [ [ f ' L r· I L [ -7 d definep as the ratio of resident support sector employment to resident plus nonresident basic sector employment, was estimated using data from Table 20. The support sector includes: resident employment in wholesale- retail trade; finance, insurance, and real estate; services; and transpor- tation, communication, and public utilities. The basic sector includes all other employment except Federal government defense-related cilivian employment. The result was a multiplier of 0.1062. This multiplier was then dis- aggregated into local and enclave multipliers, using the assumption that the enclave multiplier was equal to 0.2 times the local multiplier. This resulted in a local multiplier of 0.2332 and an enclave multiplie~ of 0.0466. The local and enclave multipliers were assumed to double (in response to major growth in the region) over.the 20 year projection period. This assumption was based on a review of similarly estimated multipliers for other regions in the state, keeping in mind the lack of interdependence between local economies of the Aleutians. The exogenous variables for which estimates must be supplied to the model include; government, construction, fisheries employment, the military, and non-OCS mining. State and local government was assumed to maintain a constant proportion to resident plus enclave employment. Federal government nondefense-related civilian employment was assumed to grow at 0.05 percent per year, in keeping with past trends. Military 101 and related federal civilian employment was assumed to maintain current levels (based on a review of historic data). Data on the growth o.f fisheries was based on information contained in Sea Grant (1980) and figures supplied to ISER by OCS, as discussed above. Construction was assumed to respond to the rapid growth of fisheries. Total construction was set at 0.21 times resident fisheries employment, where the ratio was developed by assuming that construction to total employment ratios for the Aleutians will approximate that of the State in the future. Resident construction employment is set at 5 percent of total construction initially, as indicated by prior analysis, and grows to 15 percent of total construction employment by the end of the projection period. Data for fisheries and construction employment are presented in Table 31. This completes the description of the base case assumptions. We now turn to the base case projections. 102 [ r~ L f ~ l.o [ L [j [ [ r. I L [ -~ ;....3 -> -' ..,.... .. , ::::i ' -, ,,j Year · 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 .1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 TABLE 31. PROJECTED EMPLOYMENT IN FISHERIES AND CONSTRUCTION ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: 1980-2000 Fisheries Construction {Harvesting & Processing) Resident Nonresident Resident Nonresident 6 112 563 2349 6 115 574 2313 8 134 675 2872 9 140 709 2890 10 148 752 . 2903 12 167 854 3464 14 187 959 3480 18 221 1137 3984 24 281 1453 4413 32 362 1874 4815 46 486 2535 5139 64 640 3350 5789 81 . 757 3989 5541 108 955 5048 5978 141 1167 . 6228 5976 161 1254 6736 5576 200 1464 7922 5413 242 1662 9069 5206 283 1823 10029 4742 331 2002 11110 4410 382 2162 12113 3891 SOURCE: See text. 103 The Base Case Projections The historical baseline analysis and the base case assumptions have laid the groundwork for the base projections. Before reviewing these projec- tions, it again needs to be emphasized that the projections are not forecasts of what actually will occur. These base projections are projections of economic and demographic variables, given the assumption that the specific projects, growth rates, etc., occur. As discussed above, however, there is a reasonable probability (with the exception of fisheries) that the assumptions utilized will generate a growth path that actually will be obtained or exceeded. With these comments in mind, we can now turn to the projections. THE MAP STATEWIDE BASE CASE PROJECTIONS Population Projections of populations, net migration, and natural increase are shown in Table 32, Population growth over the period averages 2.73 percent, divided about equally between the 1980s (2.68 percent) and the 1990s (2.78 percent). The 1980s begin with a relatively stable popu- lation, but from 1982-1986 growth is quite rapid (at about 5 percent). This growth is primarily a reflection of the gas pipeline construction, the waterflood project at Prudhoe Bay, the Pacific LNG plant construe- tion, and construction of a major petrochemical facility. During the 1990s construction of the Susitna hydroelectric project and fisheries expansion are the main driving forces, and the growth of population is more even. 1M f' L [ C [ L L [ [ TABLE 32. PROJECTED POPULATION AND COMPONENTS OF CHANGE: ALASKA, 1980-2000 (Thousands) F'DPTsr· 1980 400~5 1981 39'7. 94tl 1982 407.591 1983 421. 8!37 1. 9f3·4 453.74:1. 1. 98!5 -48() + 755 1986 494.9-46 1987 499.657 j_ ~~88 502. 95e:. 1989 509.16 1 SJ90 522.219 1991 538.:H2 1<:'Ci? It·-553.102 1993 567.305 1994 579.898 1995 593.178 1996 610.49 1997 629.74 1.998 648.981 j (.')QM • ~ I 7 666.24 2()00 686.394 .. SOURCE: MAP Model Projections 105 HIGNET N,:~TII-./C -6+087 ·4 v ::::57 , r···r.---o.,. .:..) .. :i / 4f.,..;-:}\f6 1. ,, 985 4.1:1.5 8 + .:!> 4.103 25 f. '74~5 4 ~ 35 .. -s 20~125 5 ·> 306 6 •) \'5()5 r::"' r\ ·" "" .Jy 7•;:)0 -3.026 6.,.{)7 -4.212 5.805 -1.,.0-4:7 57521 ~:5,) 927 ·~ -z·-·'·) ,_r v .....;C) A- 8.83 5 ... 534 7.187 5 + 7ii'!) 6.418 ~) ~ 982 ·4 + 62~5 6.141 5. :L 98 6 + ~~2"7 9.092 6.~)4:l 10.741 6 .• 613 10.:381 6 .. 939. 8.0/'1 7.24 10.:73~:5 /' + 43'? ' POPST = State Population MIGNET = Net Migration NATINC = Natural Increase Natural population increases are fairly steady over the entire period. In contrast net migration shows strong swings in response to fluctuation in labor demand associated with big project construction. The net result is a population of 685.6 thousand in 2000, an increase of 71 percent over the 1980 population of 400.3 thousand. Of this increase 119.9 thousand is accounted for by natural increase, while the balance is attributed to net migration. Employment Projections of employment for total employment (EM99ST}, wage and salary employment (EM98ST), the support sector (EMSlST), government (EMG9ST), and the basic sector (EMBlST), are presented in Table 33. Total employ- ment grows from 186.68 thousand in 1980 to 381.41 thousand in 2000, a growth rate of 3.64 percent. Growth of basic sector employment (at 5.3 percent) occurs in response to construction, expanding petroleum-related activity, and growth of bottomfishing. Expansion is somewhat more rapid in the first decade (6.0 percent) compared to the 1990s (4.6 percent). Government growth (1.67 percent) is largely accounted for by growth of State and local government. Support sector growth is strong and reflects the growth of the basic sector. For the entire period, growth averages 5.2 percent but is somewhat more rapid (at 5.8 percent) during the 1980s than during the 1990s (4.6 percent). Support sector employment as a percent of total employment grows from 33 percent in 1980 to 44 percent in 2000. 106 [ !' r-, r r ~ ! ' L f~ L r~ L [ [ L [·~ . ' _, [ L I I L [ d \,. __, 0 -.....! t ,.,J k, , J l, .< J ~,,,:,,u L,,,,.,J L,.,,,J ,:, .I.,J l,, "' J L , J I· .. J Ll :1. '?80 :1. 9i:l:l. :1. '.182 191:33 1984 :1. '?8!:5 :1. 98,1> TABLE 33. PROJECTED EMPLOYMENT: ALASKA, 1980-2000 (Thousands) Ei'19'1~3T EH9BST EriS1ST ENG9HT 1.B6. 9!'59 :1. 7 2 • ~J !'.'i :1. 6:1. .49 B3.4'76 :I.B8.~.:i9f.> :1. '7:J. s)::! 4 <!> :J. f' ~:.) :J. ~::i f.l4.~~7El :l9ci. ::);?)3 :1. B :l. ~5!'5 f.l4. :t::.!9 84. '7!:52 ~!()f:J •· ;:)48 1 9 ~~! • 'J :1. !'.'i '70.4f.l:l i:J -4 • f.>? ~!3 :L t '.i>')l 2:1.~5.694 84. B3:·:s fl2. :324 ENB:I.~lT ;.~7 + 30!:5 2B. 0~:! ~12.669 :37 + 7f.>!5 4B • !:537 247.582 230.741 99.298 83.653 47.79 252.067 235.845 104.147 87.392 44.307 ....... 1-28./.' :.__ ____ ....,:·:> !i3 .... .2.28----:2.36 ..... l-9-4--:L0.3 .... 2/.'..<.L ___ 9i41)2-'.Y.~' --42....-fW!:5 . :1.98fJ :1.9B9 1990 :L s>'J :1. :l9<?2 1. s>n> :1. 9'?4 :1.99!'.) :L996 199'7 :L99i:J :L 9 'l<'r :woo 254.72 44.176 ~~~ :":> '7 t l> ~·5 !:=j :1.02 • ~:!Bc:i '7' :L • :1. I' 2 2!:W. 97B 26i:l. 7()!:j :~!BO. 43B 290.76<J. ~:)()0 t 493 ::wa. 996 ::~ :1. i:}. :1. 'li:l :3::~0. ::)49 :'54~:~. 60'7 :3 !:.:i 6 ~ 5 ~.:j 7 :367. 9~~B ~:) f:~ :1. • !:) (~) :~! 241.. '749 ::1:::; :L • :1. :::;::s 26;;.!. !:)04 ;;~7:?. t !'504 2f:l J. • 92:'5 ~:~9(). 1. t:i3 ~.!99. MJ-4 ~~ :L 0 • i:l'? ;;! ~:~2:3 t '?4:1. :?i:36. ~51. f.l :':l-4/' • :·56B ::~ ,1> () • 6 ~:?. 2 --·. .. ... -· 10:'5.1'B2 :lO'?.S.'Of.J :1.:1.3 t 9:3!'.) 1. :1. 9. i:l~5!:5 :1. 2~.). 29? l29.BH4 :L ;;s 4 • !'.50 9 1.40.c>7cS 14EJ. o::~::) :1. ~:.:j !:=i ~ :i :?. ~:j :Ud. !'592 :L f.>B. :1. 6!'.5 .. 92.f.>T7 94.327 96. :1.6!:'i 'i'B.J.-4:1. :I.00.24i:l :l 02. 6:?.:'.'i :1. 0•1. 6 ~m :L06.37B :l ()i:J. 4;;.! :1. :L :1. (). f.J9-4 u ~:> • 6 s> '? l1. !:5 ~ 9\~)~:J 4B.91.'i> !:)2. 404. ::54+ ~)()l:j !:5 c:'> + ~'.) '?i:l ~.)'7 t 65:'.) ~59.91./' 6::->.8:1.9 6/'.:Wc') '70.09''} '?2.077 76.49 I J l. EM99ST = Total State Employment (Including mi 1 itary & ·self-employed) EM98ST =Wage & Salary Employment (State total) EMSlST =Transport, Communications, & Public Utility Employment; Wholesale-Retail Trade; Finance, · Insurance & Real Estate; & Services (State total) EMG9ST =Federal, State, & Local Government Employment (State total) EMBlST =Basic Sector Employment (State total) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections J' L ' j In summary, the projections indicate a 20 year period of sustained growth. However, the first 10 years tend to be more volatile and re- flect the concentration of several major projects in the 1982-1986 period. The 1990s growth in employment is somewhat more evenly paced, responding largely to growth in fisheries and the construction of the Susitna hydropower project. Personal Income, Wages and Prices Personal income projections (measured in 1980 dollars), both total and per capita, are shown in Table 34. Total personal income grows from 4183.5 million dollars in 1980 to 13,414.7 million dollars in 2000, an average annual rate of growth of 6.0 percent. As was the case with other variables considered, the rate of growth for the first 10 years (6.9 percent) is somewhat higher than for the second 10 years (5.1 percent). In part this reflects a somewhat lower rate of growth in employment, but it also is a result of changes in the composition of economic activity. This is more clearly seen in the data on per capita income. Over the first decade per capita income grows at an annual rate of 4.1 percent, while for the 1990-2000 period the rate of growth is only 2.3 percent. This decline is attributable to two factors. First, an increasing share of total employment is accounted for by support sector activity, with relatively lower real wages than the economy as a whole. Second, much of the growth of basic sector employment during the 1990s is in fish- eries, again an industry with relatively low wage rates. 108 f' b c L L c [ [ H [ L [ r I L L _; ' -, 1 ;::_; ' ~ ~~ ' .J ~-~ .J TABLE 34. PROJECTED TOTAL AND PER CAPITA REAL· · PERSONAL INCOME: ALASKA, 1 980-2000 (Personal Income in Millions of 1980 Dollars, Per Capita Income in 1980 Do 11 a rs) PII=i:ST F' IF:PCST 1980 4199.89 104B6~6 1.981 -4::-i 1. .7 + :35 10/'94.8 1982 4702.6 j_ 153/'. 6 1983 ~5:5?5 + f.)3 :l2742.8 1984 7l05.73 15'660 ·> 3 1985 79fl9. 46 :L6639.4 1986 7768.98 15696.6 1987 7426.66 14863.5 1.988 7499.95 149J.:l.B 1989 7693.:1.8 1~):1.09.!5 1990 8142.64 15~592 ~ ·4 19.9:1. 8690.42 16142.9 1992 9175.56 16589.3 1993 9603.43 1.6928-)2 1994 9926.27 17117.2 1995 10370.8 1748~5 + 4 1996 1101.:1 .• :1. 18036.5 1997 11686.2 18557.1. 1998 12284.5 1.8928,-9 1999 12748.5 1. 91.35 + 2000 13427.4 1956:2.:2 ... -----------·-·-·---··- SOURCE: MAP Model Projections PIRST =Personal Real Income (State total) PIRPCST-Real Per Capita Personal Income (State total) 109 Variation in the overall· growth of total and per capita personal income is also evident in the projections. Both grow steadily from 1980-1985 and then drop. It is not until 1990 that real total personal income exceeds its 1985 level and not until 1993 that per capita income reaches its 1985 level. Thereafter, both series grow steadily upward. Projection of wages and salaries, including: government wages and salaries (WSG9RST), support sector wages and salaries (WSSlRST), and basic sector wages and salaries (WSBlRST) are shown in Table 35. Total government wages grow at an overall rate of 5 percent with the growth rate for the first 10 years (5.1 percent) slightly above the second period (4.8 percent). ·Support sector wages grow at a rate of 7.4 per- cent during the 1980s, and the rate drops to 5.1 percent during the 1990s. For the period as a whole the rate is 6.2 percent. Basic sector wages grow somewhat more rapidly, especially during the first 10 years (9.5 percent) reflecting both the slightly higher rate of growth of employment and higher wage rates. During the next 10 years, the rate drops to 5.6 percent and is slightly above that of the support sector. Again, this is primarily a result of the lower wage rates in fisheries. The wage bills in the basic and support sectors mirror the pattern of growth seen in personal income. Both series peak in 1985 and then 110 r~· L [ E [ G D [ L L r . I l- L TABLE 35. PROJECTED WAGES AND SALARIES: -ALASKA, 1980-2000 (Millions of 1980 Dollars) L~SG91=(ST L<.ISS1f-i:ST L·JSBH<ST 1'780 :!.545. 9~~ 11. 1. ;:s _, 1.5 768.,:':i3'7 1?:31 :1.602.94 1123. 7 799 + 8:_) 1982 1666.83 119?.95 986.,416 1 '~'83 :t/'59.29 1391. .... 02 1 ~288 ~ ()2 1'784 1 0 '-~ --.-(-· .t..•O...:)t-~'1 189~3.:22 2l':f3v5/1 1985 20;24. 97 23l /' + ~)8 2~54;-5.1'1 1'786 :,::1.5/' + 4-4 231.3~22 1945.65 1987 22!53 ~ 87 :~1i:17 + "?6 1668.55 1988 23~11 .:1 .. 214~:). 1.9 :1.691 .61 1989 2429.03 216)' +~5-4 1 -.--, -· l .. ..: .1 ~32 1990 '1r-,-•.,-·-. -Y!.7 ~:..~,j/ ~.W .. J 22-:SO. 64 1088.04 1991 2663. 1 2411 ,.. .. r, + ,::. 7 2071 • o::; 1. 99:2 2796 • .. , ... :.:~55:7.71. 2191. 17 .L ;_) • l993 2932.:37 2684.49 22/'5·]'··4· 1994 oov •••• ""71"') __ ,,.., ~lJ;·,:_v-/.~::.. r}-"""ll:!"' . ..:./ / ,; . 16 2302.96 :J.9<t5 3213.45 28t1~) ~ 77 2-<U 9. 97 1996 33.53 <-E~~i 3054.49 26:3t\. 33 1997 --.. ,-.,.~ '") ..:>..J,:..7+.:.. 3:247+61 2835.02 1998 3/'03.93 :->420. 4/' 27'73. 69 1999 ::.'~884 .1/' 3550.95 3()37 .; ~51 2000 4063.33 3716.09 325C) • 5:~ SOURCE: MAP Model Projections WSG9RST =Government Wages & Salaries (State total) WSSlRST =Support Sector Wages & Sal~ries (State total) WSBlRST =Basic sector Wages & Salar1es (State total) 111' i decline steadily for 3 years and then begin growing again. Support sector wages reach peak 1985 levels in 1991, but it is not until 1995 that basic sector total wages equal those obtained in 1985. Thereafter the growth is steady. Projections for real wage rates are shown in Table 36. These include the real wage rates for the basic sector (WRBlRST), government (WRG9RST), and the support sector (WRSlRST). Basic sector real wages increase rapidly during the first 10 years (3.27 percent per year) and drop to 1.0 percent thereafter. Overall, the growth rate is 2.13 percent. Support sector .real wage rates grow at an average annuaT rate of 1.0 percent over the 20 year period with the rate at 1.47 percent for the 1980s. During the 1990s the rate is only 0.54 percent. Government real wages show the greatest growth at 3.24 percent over the entire period. During the 1980s the rate is 3.8 percent and drops to 2.7 percent in the · 1990s. The cycli·cal pattern of growth observed earlier is again ap- parent. It is also worth noting that our discussion of income and wages has been in real terms. Over this period inflation has been substantial. The USCPI has grown at an average rate of 8.4 percent. For the 1980s the rate was 8.5 percent and during the 1990s the rate was 8.3 percent. These rates exceeded the growth in the Alaska index which grew at 7.9 percent over the 20 year period. For the 1980s and 1990s the rates were, respectively, 8.1 and 7.7 percent (see Table 37). 112 [ [' [ r [ [ [~ r L [ L [ c 8 [ [ r L .. --· --- :J _,; SOURCE: WRBlRST = --' WRG9RST = WRSlRST = TABLE 36. PROJECTED REAL WAGE RATES: ALASKA~ 1980-2000 ( 1980 Do 11 a rs ) WRB1F;ST WfW'7'RST 1980 28063.8 1El5:t9.4 198:1. 28535-) 18997 .. 1982 30193.8 19667.2 1983 3,4106<) 20778.3 1984 45193.8 22.!\3··4· + 'i :l985 49041.8 24206.8 1986 43913.4 24686.9 1987 -38907.5 25034.9 1CJ88 38292.2 25571.4 1989 38006.4 26209.7 1990 38595.6 26899.7 1991 39520.4 27693. "1992 40198.8 2849:1 .• :1. 1.993 4 .. """"'1~("'\ -V.,j..J 7 + ./ 29251.1 1994 39943.7 2994:t.3 l.995 40388.4 30704.3 1996 41309.7 316:21.6 :1.997 42134. 32~)5l. + 1998 42421.5 33400.6 1999 4214:2.5 34161.8 2000 42574.7 35038.3 ----... ... .,. ___ , ___ . MAP Model Projections Basic Sector Real Wage Government Real Wage Support Sector Real Wage 113 v;F;S1RST 18135.4 l826:7o)1 18680.3 :l9736.2 22316.9 23339.8 2:~21 :L + 1 21182.9 20952-t8 :~0883 ·~ 6 209·49 4 7 21.163.8 2:1.340. 21425., 21:~ .. 56.5 21454.,1 21.712.9 21938+:~ 22021.3 2:1.974.,.8 22097 + "7 TABLE 37. PROJECTED ALASKA AND U.S. PRICE INDEXES: 1980-2000 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 199:i. 1992 1993 1994 1995 1.996 1997 1998 1999 2000 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections RF'I USCPI 35·4·) 65~5 2-45 y 2s;·::~ 388.45!5 269 ~ ~:):76 42~). 483 294.916 ~-157 + ~)26 32() + 279 496.964 34!5.581 529.6'?7 372.88:1. 568.09 404.203 614. 438 ·> ~36 663.687 474.959 715.79 513.906 771.758 556.56 830 +~51. 9 602. 7!53 892.902 652.781 960. ?1.7 706 + 96:l 1034.07 76~3 + f->39 :l11.3.K) 829.186 1200.21 898.008 1292.68 972.542 1392.14 105~5. 2l> 1499.48 :1. :1.40 + 68 1616.84 1235.36 RPI = Alaska Relative Price Index USCPI = U.S. Consumer Price Index 114 r [ [ [ [ r~ [ I- I L [ _j _j _, ;j Government Revenues and Expenditures - State government revenue projections by source are shown in--Table 38. The variables include: total State government revenues (REVGFR)~ petro- leum revenues (RP9SR), revenues from the Federal government (RFDSR)~ and other revenues (RNDSR),. Total revenue grows steadily from 1980 (2.3 billion dollars) to a peak of 5.9 billion dollars in 1991 and declines steadily thereafter to 4.7 billion dollars in 2000. The bulk of these revenues are accounted for by petroleum revenues. After steady growth these peak in 1989 (at 3.6 billion dollars) and decline through the year 2000 to a level of 1.2 billion dollars. Receipts from the Federal government decline throughout the period~ frow 0.2 billion in 1980 to 0.07 billion dollars in 2000. Other revenues increase steadily and substantially from a level of 0.2 billion dollars in 1980 to over 3.4 billion dollars in 2000. These revenues include such items as: corporate income taxes~ personal income taxes~ earnings on fund balances~ and miscellaneous tax receipts. Expenditure data are presented in Table 39 and include total State government real expenditures (E99SR) and real per capita expenditures (E99SRPC). Total expenditures grow at 5.7 percent over the entire period and at 5.5 percent for the first 10 years. During the 1990s the rate is slightly higher at 5.9 percent. The growth is relatively stable throughout. 115 SOURCE: ! TABLE 38. PROJECTED STATE GOVERNMENT REVENUES: 1980 1981. 1982 198~} l S.1 f3-4 :J.·:NJ5. 1986 1987 1988 1. S'89 1990 1.991 1992 1.993. 1994 199~5 l<;il}6 1. <J'-?7 1998 1999 2000 ALASKA, 1980-2000 (Millions of 1980 Dollars) . REVGFR RP<fSR RFDSfi: 2261.48 1823 ~ ·<lt) 226 ~ 92·4 30?8.93 2671 .. 92 206 + 99~5 3418 .. 73 2837.4 1 Q'"> '")•/r.7 , ·I.,:_ {oo A.,,:_~ 3786.51 3016 .. 41 1.82 .. 06!:5 4102.89 3074 .. 91 1 /'~} .. 905 4629.05. 33·4/' v-:=~ .. ·---17 l-t--6i3:~- 5032f-·42 3507.34 1.63.3:54 5274.69 35J4~)-:-152vl22 5498.34 3~)/"]5 + 76 14:1..38:1. 5752 + ]'1 3627.67 :1.~52.21.9 5807.75 :34681-27 1.2·4 + 8~~6 5865fo1 3309.33 118.534 57~51 + ~)3 2984.34 112.406 564~-) + 89 27()2. 58 106.399 5493.31 2402.9 100. 4~58 5341. 9!5 21.39.36 94.B 5204.76 191.2.38 89.857 508i3 .. 2 1708.92 85. :~7 4970.27 1520.71. 81 .• 072 4841. + 0!'5 1347.7 76.769 4719.95 1192.99 72.821 RNDSR 2:1.1 + 104 ~~00 ., Oj.? 389d07 5<38 .. 029 B52.069 .:1.110. 07 . -- 1361.74 1!'577. 57 1781..19 1992.82 2214.65 2~l37 .2-4 2654.79 2834.92 2989.98 3107.8 I 3202.53 3293.9 3368.49 :~416 .. 58 3454.13 MAP Model Projections REVGFR = Total State Government Revenues RP9SR = Petroleum Revenues RFDSR = Revenues from the Federal Government RNDSR = Other Revenues 116 [ [ [ [ [ [~ [ I' L [ [ [ [ L [ l fe L r L [ ·-, ~ ~ ., ~ .. , . ..- ., ,.; _J ::_::] .., : ~ d TABLE 39. PROJECTED TOTAL AND PER CAPITA STATE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURES: ALASKA, 1980-2000 (Millions of 1980 Dollars) · E'.f'9SR E99SRPC 1 1?80 1489.56 1101.03 198:1. 1.550.34 1147.55 1982 1.62:l..2 11.77 .. 49 1983 :1.711.4 1200.97 1984 1. 795.38 1171.37 1985 19:20.26 1182.44 1986 2041 .1.4 1220.85 1987 2152.91 1.275 ~56 1988 22~7 0 ~58 1336~45 1989 2400.04 1.395 .. 43 1.990 2537.6:3 1-438.5-4 1991. 2cS88.21 1478.26 1992 2850 •. -o:}5 1525,.65 1993 3020.14 1.576-> :L 994 3198.71 1.632.93 1995 3385 + ·41 1689.55 1996 35H1.6 :1.736 .. 78 1997 3790.97 1782. :L:I. 19~>8 4012.94 1830.53 1999 4247.27 :1.887.23 2000 4490.41 1936.68 -~.-.. SOURCE: MAP Model Projections E99SR = State Government Real Expenditures E99SRPC = Real Per Capita State Government Expenditures 117 ·~- I Growth of real per capita expenditures is more erratic and reflects the fluctuation in population observed earlier. Expenditures first peak in 1983, decline and rise again throughout the period, and surpass the 1983 peak in 1986. Overall growth is at an average annual rate of 2.87 percent with growth at 2.7 percent during the 1980s rising to 3.01 percent in the 1990s. The fund balance also accumulates throughout the period, in nominal terms. However, in real terms the fund peaks in 1996 and declines thereafter (see Table 40). 118 [ r·· I' L [ [ [ [ [j [ [ TABLE 40. PROJECTED FUND BALANCES IN CURRENT AND 1980 DOLLARS: ALASKA, 1980-2000 19:31 1983 19:34 :L '7'8!5 198C) 198~;.· 1988 1. 9Fi9 1.990 1.991. 1992 1. 99:3 1.994 1995 1996 :1.997 1998 :1.999 2000 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections FUND = Fund Balance FUNDR = Real Fund Balance FUND FUNDF( 19~:)0.41 ·40<)5 v -4/' 13713.,7 1!3505. 24156.2 30542.1 37698.8 45)'35v·4 5-4:~:;.':3 I) 8 633<)3 ~ 5 72364.6 81.423.4 9027~) ., :1. 1 tl~58 •) ·6·4 34B:3. 1.1 !:)28() +51 7271 + ()9 9321.4(5 11.800 ~ <_;· 14363.,.7 16802.9 19187.5 2:L5f~3v5 2::~75!~i <" 5 :~5:7-<"t7v3 28629+1 2~?4f~9 + 7 98812.4 29967.2 1.070Et05 30103.2 1.:L46Et05 29956.9 1.217Et05 29525.3 1.279Et05 28803.5 1.330E+05 27787.9 119 i The Base Case: The Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest Regions In this section we review the base case projections for the Anchor- age (RS), Southcentral (R4), and Southwest (R2) Regions. Projections for the Aleutian Islands Census Division are included in the following section. Population Population projections for the three regions are shown in Table 41. Population growth in the regions reflects the general level of projected growth for the regions. For the 1980-2000 period growth in Region 2 and Region 4 exceeds that of the state; Region 2 growth occurs largely in response to rapid expansion of bottomfishing, and is concentrated i~ the 1990-2000 period where the growth rate is 6.31 percent. Growth in Region 4 reflects construction of the LNG plant and petroleum-related activity. Growth tends to be more rapid in the 1980-1990 p~riod (at 3.61 percent per year) and tapers off to 2.01 percent from 1990-2000. Region 5 (Anchorage) population declines moderately until 1982, and then grows at a rate of 2.76 percent for the remainder of the decade. Growth is similar (at 2.83 percent) throughout the 1990s. As a result of the population growth, minor changes in regional popula- tion shares occur. In Region 2 population.grows from 6.7 percent of total population to 9.6 percent, while Anchorage declines from 49 percent to 44.6 percent. Region 4 population as a percentage of the state remains at about 11.2 percent. 120 [ [ [ [ B [ [ ,- L L ··' -' _; SOURCE: TABLE 41. PROJECTED REGIONAL POPULATION: 1980-2000 (Thousands) c - POPR2 POPR4 POF'R5 198() 1. 981 :L982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1 !:)'"'"'? .,o.,. 1.988 1989 1990 1991 19'72 1993 1994 1995 19'-16 199/' 1998 1.999 2000 MAP Model Projections '1··· q:r::-· ..:.0 + .. .J -<'t·4 ~ 5-4~7 1. 96 .. 154 27.186 ~:}5.; 48·4· 188 ~ 5~56 27.451 47~076 187~061. 27.017 48 .. 569 191 ~521 26¥ ·424 52.082 206~01.8 27.694 55.,694 2:L 9 ~ 9~)-4 2'~ + ,.S9 60 .. 131 225+ ·467 30.724 62.499 224.,861 31.Cl()~5 '""l "'"1't-"\ A o...::. ~o·•t 225~1l~2 33 + 33'7' 62.928 227 .3·4~5 -.. 1::" -"J"7 / ,.."'h.}+,/,/ 0 6~5 + 497 231 + 6~=36 . ...,.,."' ~~~~~ ~0 t .J-.:.) ... J 64.644 238~232 4:1. .0:1.4 6!::1.571. 245.,..089 44. 4!":5:1. •' I -t,..., oo./o.,. 251v392 48 + .\1~7 5 66 ~ 7~:.:2 256.927 49.981 67 ~577 2<53 .489 53 .. 414 69.004 2/'1..383 56.398 70.898 280.-449 59.934 72.674 289.395 63.1.01 73+885 297.,39 tl5. 993 7"?.,476 ·306.259 POPR2 = Total Population, Region 2 (Southwest) POPR4 =Total Population, Region 4 (Southcentral) POPR5 = Total Population, Region 5 (Anchorage) 121 Employment The regional growth in total employment (EM99) generally mirrors the growth in population. Employment growth, however, occurs at a slightly higher rate than population, inferring a slight increase in the employ- ment to population ratio. Growth in Region 2 (at 5.4 percent) exceeds that of either Region 4 (3.8 percent per year) or Region 5 (3.7 percent). As was the case with population, growth in Region 2 is concentrated in the 1990s, while for Region 4 growth of employment is more rapid during the 1980s. Growth in Anchorage employment tends to be more uniform, at 3.8 percent per year during the 1980s and 3.5 percent during the 1990s (see Table 42). Growth of support sector employment (EMSl) parallels growth of total employment (see Table 43), although in each case support sector employ- ment a~ a percent of total employment increases. As would be expected, the share of total employment is largest for the largest of the three regions (55 percent in Region 5) while for Southwest the share is 27 percent. For Region 4 the comparable figure is 37 percent. Total government employment (EMG) projections are shown in Table 44. Because these figures include federal civilian and military government employment (with 1 ittle net growth) the overall growth (at 1.8 percent per year) is not great for Regions 2 and 5. In Region 4, where these components of total government employment are relatively small, the overall growth rate is about 3.2 percent. The share of total employment accounted for by government declines in each region. 122 L r I L --, ---' ~ 1 ' ...l TABLE 42. PROJECTED REGIONAL TOTAL EMPLOYMENT: 1980-2000 (Thousands) EH99R2 EN99R4 1980 12.6 20~133 1981. 12.,.6~·7 2(j + 3()2 1982 1.2.831 2:!.v293 1983 12.784 2:~ + ·4·42 1984 1.2.,827 25~219 1985 13.496 27.033 1986 14.348 29.088 1 '""''"'""} 70/ 1.4. 862 29~857 1988 :1.5. -4-<l-3 ...,. .., .. , ..... ·-1' ~v.vv,;;:, 1989 16.,2?8 30.,. 53~~ 1990 17.572 3L283 1991 19.0?6 32.317 1992 20.499 ..,._. ,.., ..... ..., ~"),;).,_\}/ 1993 22+·425 •Y."l '")~.a_ .!l"'i. •'-~ • 1994 2·4 .699 3 ... -=. .362 1'1>95 25.814 35+13 1996 27.947 36.308 1997 29.903 37~756 1998 32.171 39.04 1999 34.285 39.774 2000 36.328 42+127 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections EM99R2 = Total Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EM99R4 =Total Employment, Region 4, (Southcentral) EM99R5 = Total Employment, Region 5, (Anchorage) 123 EI199F~5 83 •) :l86 83 ~ 8t1~:1 8<.~ v 48/' 91. ~ :553 101..255 1.11.448 115.569 115.38:-) :L15v395 117.216 120.755 125. 76~:) 1.30. 72 .. -~'1::"" ""i•...., l' J . .:>w.,_oo 139.:,25 143.565 148.8 :1.54.836 160.81~~ 166.165 171.808 TABLE 43. PROJECTED REGIONAL SUPPORT SECTOR EMPLOYMENT: 1980-2000 (Thousands) E'"'·~·· ... ,,.) J•f.o J.f·t .. ,:. ENS1F:4 ENS1F:5 1980 2.661 6~~~1·4 33 ~ 3•1)3 1'7'81. 2 + <S:2~:; tS.:l51. -?-.,. .--•-J>r-,:) .. ;). ;·)~");.) 1982 2. 63~s .. -s 1-2)"2 3;.:; + ·4·42 1983 2 + ~)31 6.718 3s;·. (s,s~~ 1984 2 + c"i2~:S 7 .54· ·48v266 1985 3 .. 02~5 8 + 83~-=) 56 {-!5·42 1986 3 + ~}9':1 :1.0.0:!.9 r.:-r"\ c,·-·-'-10.,. ; / / 1987 3 + ·4~'7 10.492 r.:"""! ...,_,.._, ,.}/. / ,:)/ 1988 3.593 10.293 57 .. 081 1989 3.80:1. 10.512 57.998 1990 4+176 10 + 7-47 60.374 199:1. 4.~)91 1L119 6:;. 998 1992 5 + O'-S7 11.462 67. 46<? 1993 t::" t:!"-"' .I ~•...J/0 11 .889 7CJ v 5·4· 1994 6.226 12.152 7:? ~ 0-4~1 1995 6.549 :1.2.4l>l 75.771 1.996 7.146 12.905 :?9 + ·40!5 1.997 7.7()5 13 .. 509 83 .• 687 :1.998 8 .. 447 14.113 87.81.5 1999 9.017 14 .. 686 9:1 ... 286 2000 9.638 1.5.416 95. C'32 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections EMS1R2 = Support Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMS1R4 =Support Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMS1R5 = Support Sector Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) l24 [ [ L: [' [ [ [ r L f~ L r~ l [ [J _L L [ [ I" L r~ I L [ ~_j ~ ; """ ' _; TABLE 44. PROJECTED REGIONAL GOVERNMENT EMPLOYMENT: 1980-2000 (Thousands) ' !· EI-·lG9R2 EMG9R4 EMG9R5 1980 7 + /'89 6.?1.·4 __,(_ ,, .-)-"' ,.:>,).~},·_/ 1981 7.879 7 "'"''' ..,. ~,t,;;.o -?r-... ~r:-~,:r + ,:).:) :1 <:; .. ., . ., . , 0.,;.. 7 +'73 _, P •• • •"j / + VO.<-35-~ 488 198~} -----·-7.948 7 •. 02.:.? --35~A!~i3 198-4 7.8,:H \.St67 3/.l ~ ;~·73 198!5 7.94"7 6.841 -~t::" ~ ~;_) + .. ·:.. 1986 8.2~11 7.314 36-r5 1J7 1987 8. 4:)5 7.641 37 .,.•437 1988 8.53 -"' .. "~Or::" , + 1•-J.:.) ~:;:7. f.~-4 /' 1989 8 + 6-46 7.977 38. :~>(S5 1990 8.776 8.185 38,;9-<t~::i 1991 8.91.8 8.41.6 3:;>,; 5~33 1992 '7'. Ol~? 8.664 4() ~' 25;? 1993 0 '")"jt:!"' I + 1'1-..,:....J. 8v928 40. 9/'9 1.994 9.401 s:· ·i :~~5 41.?92 1995 9 v 5~35 9 + ·485 42 ~ ,::}•=97 1996 9.687 '"' ~ 0, 7•07•=> -4~7) i\ 095 19'17 9.839 9.9~)1 ·43 y /'93 1998 10.02 1.0. 264 44.,635 1999 if)~ 224 10.62 4!5 +588 2000 10.394 10.903 46 .. 373 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections EMG9R2 = Total Government Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMG9R4 =Total Government Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) Et~G9R5 = Total Government Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) 125 Basic sector employment (EMBl) projections for each of the regions are presented in Table 45. Employment growth reflects the occurrence of major project employment in Region 4 (especially LNG and petroleum development while Region 2 responds to growth in bottomfishing. Growth of Anchorage basic employment is relatively stable over time and cap- tures the indirect basic employment of projects outside the region. Personal Income Data on real personal income (PIR) for the regions is presented in Table 46. Over the full projection period the average annual rates of . growth ~re 8.4 percent, 6.3 percent, and 5.7 percent for Regions 2, 4, and 5, respectively. Growth in the Southwest Region occurs primarily in response to expansion of bottomfishing, and is more rapid in the 1990s {at 9.9 percent) than during the 1980s (6.9 percent). For the Southcen- tral Region the pattern is reversed. Petroleum-related activity is primarily responsible for the growth rate of 8.7 percent during the 1980s. The rata drops to 4.0 percent during the 1990s. Growth of personal income in the Anchorage Region is more uniform, at 6.4 percent during the 1980s and falls slightly to 5.1 percent in the 1990s. Per capita real personal income (PIRPC) projections are included in Table 47. Growth rates of per capita income are similar, (at 3.7 per- cent, 3.4 percent, and 3.4 percent for Regions 2, 4, and 5, respectively) when looked at over the full projection period. For Regions 4 and 5, 126 [ [ L [ [ r I L r L [ [ [ f--, L r~ I L L .J TABLE 45. PROJECTED REGIONAL BASIC EMPLOYMENT: 1980-2000 (Thousands) ,. ! Ei'·HHR4 EI-!B l.f\:5 1 s;·so 1. 98:l 1.982 1'=783 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 19?0 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections 1 ... 765 1.788 1. + 9:1.7 1.977 2 + t)52 2.227 2.-415 3 + 02·4 3~538 -4.332 6 .. 084 7 + 3·46 8~795 9 ~ 4:37 :1.0 .. 845 12.094 13 + 4-42 14.784 16.04 ·4 + 035 4d57 4.93 5.629 7.874 8.:l91 8.465 8.39 8.602 8.72 9~011 9.418 9. 709 10.03 9.,614 9 + 81!5 :LO.~H9 10.883 11.232 11.036 12.322 EMBlR2 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMB1R4 =Basic Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMB1R5 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) 127 8.435 8.)588 8.~J12 10,..64 11.699 - 12.002 12.,138 12.352 1~~~632 1~';).002 :l3.472 1.4. ()37 14.597 15.11~3 15.714 16.431 17.197 17 .. 934 18.633 19.475 TABLE 46. PROJECTED TOTAL PERSONAL INCOME BY REGION: 1980-2000 (Millions of 1980 Dollars) F'IRR2 PIF~F~4 F'IF"<f<5 1'780 28·4 + ·4~~9 4l3~3!.:i~5 19i31 2\.7'() ~ 2~~t1 425.007 1982 3()2 + 95~~ 473.587 1.983 318 ~·53cj ~).49 +57 1.984 3..:~!5 .. .<f93 788 > :l95 1985 :~Cl9 ~ 1:4:3 902 •. <h)9 1986 424.979 922 + 24~5 1987 4:36.942 876.35'7 1988 459.845 881.093 198-9 495.377 9C<:·1 ~ 333 1990 55,:>. 016 011 .. "' OJ::-1=" '"'t/+7...J~J 199J. 616.382 1001. .. 55 1992 686.056 1047.23 1.993 763 + ·44~ 109~~. 66 1994 86-4 t322 1085.33 :L 99~5 9:1.(.S.52 1119.84 1996 10:1.6.73 1.179.45 1997 1107.72 1.254 •. 1998 1227t82 130:3 ·> 92 1999 1318.95 :l322. 36 2000 1429.22 1407.98 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections PIPR2 = Real Personal Income, Region 2 (Southwest)_ PIPR4 =Real Personal Income, Region 4 (Southcentral) PIPR5 = Real Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) 128 188<3.03 1939~7 2049.97 2:2<53 + '72 ~:7-46 ~ 38 31.81:'L 34 326() + 63 3196~17 32:31 .. 14 :~33·4 + 4·2 350~i .. 16 3706~73 3910.72 41.05.6~ 4269. fk) 4459.88 4699.95 4977.61 5238.02 5471./'~} 5734.68 r [ r r~ l - r r· f '\._.-->" [ r l [ [ E c t L C [ r , L __ [ TABLE 47. PROJECTED PER CAPITA REGIONAL PERSONAL INCOME: 1980-2000 (1980 Dollars) F'II:;:PCR2 PIF:F'CR·4 F' IF.:F'CF~5 1980 l C1 55~~; ~ 6 ':;'278 + <S4 9t-s25 (o 23 19G:i. 10677.8 9344.09 10288.2 198:-~ 11.036.1 10060. :L :l09!58 ~C)! 1983 11790.:!. 11315.2 :L 1.820 ·> 7 1984 13075. 1.5:1.33 + () :1.3330.8 1985 :i.40~31 -· . / 162()2 io cy l-44'75.;. 5 1986 1·4313./' :l5337. 2 1446:1. ..., . / 198~7 1.4221 .6 :l40~21 .9 142:1.4., 1988 14458.3 141.23.8 1435:1. +6 1989 1. 48!58. . .., 143~)5 • :!. 466,-:). ~i / 1.990 :1.!5541 1-6 14929. 1. :1.5128.9 19':r 1 15995.2 15A·93.) 4 15~5!5~7 + 3 1992 :1.672"7.4 15971 • 1~:5956.:.3 1993 1/':!.74.8 16~581 ..,. 16331 . r.:-- •.:i ,.-..J 1994 1 7B:~o. :1. 162c;6 ~ 3 16618.9 jOOr::' . / , .. J 18T37. 3 165?1 .•. , <).,..,: 16S:'26+3 1996 :l90;:Vf. 9 1709~~ ~ !:5 17318. !5 1997 1.9641 JJ-2 :!. /'687 + !5 17"?-48 + 7 1998 20486.,3 :!.80:1.0. 7 18099.9 1999 20902.:3 17897.6 18399~2 2000 21657. :1. 18173. 1 18724.9 SOURCE: MAP Model Projections PIRPCR2 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 2 (South\-Jest) PIRPCR4 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 4 (Southcentral) PIRPCR5 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) 129 ' ! however, the increase tends to be more rapid in the first ten years (4.9 percent and 4.6 percent, respectively), declining to 2.0 percent and 2.2 percent during the 1990s. --In summary, growth of population, employment, and income is substantial in all three regions. The specific rates of growth over time, however, vary considerably in response to the timing and occurrence of major projects and industry growth within regions. It should also be noted that much of the projected growth for Region 2 occurs in the Aleutian Islands Census Division and we now turn to a combination of projections for this area. 130 [ r- [ r L [ L [ L [ r , L r- L [ Base Case Projections: SCIMP and the Aleutian Islands Census Division As stated earlier, the major growth area within the Southwest Region is the Aleutian Islands Census Division. The driving force behind this projected growth is the assumed rapid expansion of the bottomfishing industry, as set forth in the base case assumptions. Projections of employment by sector are presented in Table 48. Employment in the support sector (EMS) is the primary endogenous series and reflects resident employment. Growth in this sector occurs at an average annual rate of 16.9 percent. This implies a doubling of support sector growth every five years. The growth rate is also quite stable, at 17.0 percent for the first half of the projection period and 16.9 per- cent during the second half. Support sector employment, as a proportion of total resident em- ployment (TE) also grows over time, rising from 25 percent in 1981 to over 33 percent in 2000~ When viewed as a proportion of total civilian and defense employment (TOTE), support sector employment grows from 6 percent to 24 percent. In both instances, the growth in the total share of employment accounted for by support sector employment reflects the growth of the multipliers over time and the general process of import substitution. In addition, it reflects the declining relative importance of nonresident employment in the region. 131 [ r-· TABLE 48. ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION EMPLOYMENT l-. PROJECTIONS: 1981-2000 [ Year EMS EHG EMA EMX TE EMM ENCLV TOTE j : 1981 400 578 588 6 1572 2523 2428 6523 1982 491 666 689 8 1854 2523 3006 7383 L 1983 522 680 723 9 1934 2523 3030 7478 1984 557 695 766 10 2028 2523 3051 7602 1985 664 787 868 12 2331 2523 3631 8485 [ 1986 728 814 973 14 2528 2523 3667 8718. 1987 869 914 1151 18 2952 2523 4205 9680 1988 1064 1029 1467 24 3584 2523 4694 10801 [ 1989 1311 1159 1888. 32 4390 2523 5177 12090 1990 1633 1321 2549 46 5579 2523 5625 13727 f' 1991 2141 1555 3364 64 7124 2523 6429 16076 1992 2471 1644 4003 81 8199. 2523 6298 17020 . L_ 1993 3095 1899 5062 108 10165 2523 6933 19621 1994 3764 2119 6242 141 12266 2523 7143 2~932 [' 1995 4101 2174 6750 161 13186 2523 6830 22539 1996 4831 2381 7936 200 15348 2523 6877 24748 [ 1997 5534 2564 8980 242 17321 2523 6868 26712 1998 6248 2712 10043 283 19286 2523 6565 28374 1999 7044 2888 11124 331 21387 2523 6412 30322 [ 2000 7815 3026 12127 382 23350 2523 6053 31926 [ [ L~ ' SOURCE: SCIMP Projections. L L C' L r· I 132 L [ ~--) -'. ~· Civil ian nondefense-related federal governme_nt and state and local government (EMG) grow steadily over the period, at an average annual rate of 9.1 percent. The bulk of the growth is accounted for by ex- panding state and local government in response to ~egional growth and averages 11 percent per year. Resident employment in manufacturing and commercial fishing is included in variable EMA and reflects the projected growth of bottom- fishing. Growth averages 17.3 percent over the projection period. The growth rate is greater than that for the fisheries industry itself, since an increasing proportion of total fisheries employment, over time, is assumed to be resident employment. Enclave employment (ENCLV) is the other variable reflecting fisheries growth_ (ENCLV includes nonresident construction). Enclave-fisheries employment includes nonresident employ- ment in both harvesting and processing. During the first half of the projection period, enclave fisheries employment grows at about 9.8 per- cent; while during the second half of the projection period, it grows at less than one percent annually. This is because of the substitution of resident for nonresident participation in the fisheries industry. Resident construction employment (EMX) also reflects the rapid growth of employment and population. It grows at about 24 percent per year. This very rapid growth is in part due to the substitution of resident for nonresident employment over time and also reflects a modest increase in the share of construction to total resident employ- ment. 133 Total resident employment (TE) grows at a rate of 15.3 percent per year over the projection period and is relatively stable throughout the whole period .. Military and defense-related civilian employment (EMt1) was assumed to be constant, and so there is no growth in this sector. Total employment (TOTE) is the sum of total resident employment plus EMM and ENCLV employment. Because of the "no growth" assumption for EMM and the relatively low growth rate of ENCLV (4.9 percent) resident employ- ment as a percent of total employment grows over time, from 24 percent in 1980 to 73 percent in 2000. Population projections for the Aleutians are contained in Table 49. Total resident civilian population (BPOPP) grows from 3,777 in 1981 to 41,597 by 2000. The average annual rate of growth for the entire period is 13.5 percent. Over the first half of the period population growth averages 12.5 percent; while for the second half, the growth rate in- creases slightly to 14.4 percent. Total population for the census division (BASPP) includes, in addition to BPOPP, military and defense-related civilian government employees and dependents plus enclave employees. Total population grows from 10,595 in 1981 to 52,040 in 2000, at an average annual rate of 8.7 percent. Growth during the second half of the projection period occurs at a somewhat higher rate (9.6 percent), reflecting the growth of enclave employment relat~d to development of the bottomfishing industry. 134 [ [ [ r~ L [ [ [ [ E L L L ' L -~ __ [ remainder of the projection period is less than 0.1 percent. In the case of government (WRG9RST) the difference is even less, growing from · less than 2 dollars in 1983 to 155 dollars in 1988 (a 0.6 percent dif- ference). Th~reafter the difference drops quickly, and over the last several jears the difference is actually marginally negative. Tables 58 and 59 contain the detailed data. Changes in the Alaska Relative Price Index (RPI) are minimal. A slight increase over the base case (approximately 0.1 percent) occurs in the early of the project, but before the project peaks the differential becomes negative (by about 0.3-0.5 percent). Statistically the differences are probably not significant and for all intents and pur- poses there is no real effect on the index. Data on the index are included in Table 60. GOVERNMENT REVENUE AND EXPENDITURES The impact of the mean case scenario is highly limited. The maximum difference in total state government revenues (REVGFR) is about 1.7 percent in 1990 and 1991, and averages about 1.4 percent from 1993 through the end of the projection period. The impact on petroleum revenues (RP9SR) and federal government revenue (RFDSR) are slightly greater. Differences in petroleum revenues peak at about 62 million dollars in 1990 and decline thereafter to about 35 million dollars in 2000. However, because petroleum revenues in general are declining, the percentage difference between the mean and base case tends to grow, increasing to about 2.9 percent by 2000. Differences in revenue from 151 TABLE 58. PROJECTED STATEWIDE REAL ~~AGE RATE IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE / WRB1RST-EXOGENOUS WRS1RST-EXOGENOUS WRG9RST -EXOGENOUS 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1 "'~" 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 MEAN 0. o. 0. 17.52 7 40.508 182.301 235.363 1168.26 1363.79 1214.65 909.027 330.098 155.125 188.965 21o.957 ?1:. 7<1? .207 .1 ~5 222.078 249.176 264.793 258.695 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 ; 1989 f 1990 I 1991 ~ 1992 l 1993 I ~ ;;i \ 1996 1997 1 1998 1999 I 2000 I MEAN 0. o. 0. 4.988 11.699 37.937 •54.477 258.509 335.926 279.574 ~94.531 53.797 0.402 5.035 10.57 13.094 12.055 12.887 16.566 18.316 WRBlRST = Basic Sector Real Wage WRSlRST = Support Sector Real Wage WRG9RST = Government Real Wage SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 152 1980 1981 1982 1983 1::384 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1 991 1992 1993 1994 1!::)!::):;, 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 MEAN 0. 0. o. 1.672 5.488 16.844 24.504 102.945 154.937 118.242 71.027 -5.535 -48.742 -44:34 -42.613 -q:.!.~l -45.C12 -47.047 -48.867 -49.633 -50.719 r [ [ r [ [ [ [ [ G [ I' L r~ I L L ·~ , I\ -, --- -, -' ' " ~ ,.., TABLE 59. PROJECTED STATEWIDE REAL t~AGE RATE IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE WRB1RST-EXOGENOUS WRS1 RST -EXOGENOUS 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 . ---.-:;~..,~ 1996 1997 1998- 1999 2000 MEAN MEAN o. 1980 0. o. 1981 o. o. 1982 0. 0.051 1983 0.025 0.09 1984 0.052 0.372 1985 0.163 0.536 1986 0.245 3.0C3 1987 1.22 3.562 1588 1.603 3.196 1989 1 .339 2.355 1990 0.929 0.835 . 1991 0.254 0.338 1992 0.002 0.468 1993 0.024 0,541 1994 0.049 ':"'--1995 0.062 V • -J-.J I 0.501 1996 0.06 0.527 1997 0.055 0.567 -1998 0.059 0.628 1999 Q.075 0.608 2000 0.083 WRBlRST = Basic Sector Real Wage WRSlRST = Support Sector Real Wage WRG9RST = Government Real Wage SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 153 WRG9RST - 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1935 1986 1987 1968 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1 0'?'- 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 EXOGENOUS MEAN 0. 0. o. 0.008 0.024 0.01 0.099 0. 411 0.606 0.451 0.264 -0.02 -o .111 -o .152 -o .142 -n 14 -o. 142 -o .145 -0.146 -0.145 -0.145 TABLE 60. PROJECTED STATEWIDE RELATIVE PRICE INDEX IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE AND PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE Absolute Difference RPI -EXOGENOUS MEAN 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 0.096 1934 0.336 1985 0.562 1986 0.41 1987 -0.34 1988 -1.717 1989 -2.851. 1990 -3.812 1991 -4.293 1992 -3.982 1993 -3.663 1994 -3.563 1995 -3.633 1996 -3.752 1997 -3.793 1 998· -3.843 1999 -3.977 2COO -4.119 i \. ! Percentage Difference RPI -EXOGENOUS MEAN 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 0.021 1984 . 0.068 1985 0.106 1986 0.072 1987 -o.o55 1968 -0.259 1589 -0.:398 1990 -0.494 1991 -0.517 1992 -0.446 1993 -0.381 1994 -0.345 1\:1!:1!:1 -U • ..:l:.!to 1996 -0.313 1997 -0.293 1998 -0.276 1999 -0.265 2000 . -0.255 RPI = Alaska Relative Price Index SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 154 [ [ [ [ r L r L [ [ [ r- I L L the federal government peak at about 3.4 million dollars and then decline steadily. In terms of percentage differences it is 2.8 percent in 1990 and averages about 1.9-2.0 percent for most of the 1990s. Other state government revenues, including state corporate income taxes and earnings on fund balances (RNDSR) are moderately impacted. The percehtage difference (mean over base case) grows to about 1:5 percent in 1990, and amounts to about 33 million dollars. The difference declines slightly, and the average difference over most of the 1990s is about 1.0 percent. (See Tables 61 and 62 for supporting data.)· Total real state government expenditures (E99SR) i~crease somewhat as a result of expanded population resulting directly and indirectly from the mean case scenario. The difference amounts to 81.7 million dollars in 1990, drops somewhat, but begins to increase again by the end of the projection period. In terms of percentage differences the peak differ- ential (3.2 percent) is reached in 1990, and drops steadily thereafter, to about 2~20 percent by the year 2000. Per capita real state govern- ment expenditures (E99SRPC) are not impacted, and the percent difference remains constant at 0.0 percent. Impacts on the real fund balance (FUNDR) are also modest. Under the mean case scenario the balance is about 152 million dollars, or 0.6 percent above the base case in 1992. After this peak the differential drops steadily and is about 0.3 percent by 2000. Data for the state government expenditure and fund balance variables are contained in Tables 63 and 64. 155 TABLE 61. PROJECTED STATEWIDE REVENUE & FUND IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE MEAN FUNDR - 1980 1981 1982 1983 1584 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 "! ~~= 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 REVGFR RP9SR RFDSR RNDSR o. o. 0. o. o. 0. o. o. o. o. 0. o. -0.644 -0.633 0.064 -0.076 -2.145 -2.077 0.109 -0.175 -3.109 -3.549 0.28 0.16 -0.016 -2.528 0.556 1 .959 14.516 6.537 1. 551 6.428 42.129 22.889 2.592 16.649 79.719 50.673 3.375 25.669 98.418 61 .681 3.474 33.261 99.379 60.54 3.064 35.775 89.992 55.559 2.574 31.859 81.754 51 .328 2.259 28.167 77.676 48.056 2.066 27.551 7.:.:-:s ~5 .. '!~7 ~ .. <?~= 213:1.335. 74.113 43.146 1.781 29.188 72.391 40.847 1.676 29.868 ; 71.156 38.679 1 .594 30.883 70.508 36.676 1.502 32.331 69.672 34.7 1.401 33.573 REVGFR = Total State Government Revenues RP9SR = Petroleum Revenues 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1966 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 .. 1""' ... -• .;!.,t,j 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 RFDSR = Revenues from the Federal Government RNOSR = Other Revenues FUNDR = Real Fund Balance SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 156 I EXOGENOUS MEAN o. o. o. -2.77 -10.395 -21.922 -26.C'62 -15.797 19.289 64.961 113.281 147 .ass 151.785 147.828 144.641 !~~ .:~~ 136.523 124.996 109.281 92.051 72.387 [ [ [ I L [ L [ [ l [ r, L L MEAN -, 1980 "-' 1981 1982 ' 1983 1994 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 ~ 1993 1994 _; 1 ~9~ 1996 1997 1998 1599 2000 ""' -~ .J .....J d TABLE 62. PROJECTED STATEHIDE REVENUE & FUND IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE '·' , I\ FUNOR -EXOGENOUS REVGFR RP9Srt RFDSR RNDSR MEAN o. 0. 0. o. 1980 0. o. . o. 0. o. 1981 0. o. 0. 0. o. 1982 0. -o. 01 1 -0.021 0.035 -o .01 3 1983 -0.038 -0.052 -o. oss 0.062 -0.021 1984 -0.112 -o. 067 -0.106 0.163 0.014 1985 -o .186 -o. -0.072 0.34 0.144 1986 -0.181 0.275 0.184 1 .02 0.407 1987 -0.094 0.766 0.64 1.833 0.935 1988 0. 101 1 .336 1.397 2.553 1 .288 1989 0.301 1 .595 1. 7i8 2.783 1 .502 1990 0.477 1.694 1 .829 2.585 1.468 1991 0.574 1.565 1.862 2.29 1.2 . 1992 0.554 1.449 1.899 2.123 0.994 1993 0.516 1. 414 2. 2.057 0.921 1994 . 0.49 • 111? ? 1');::; ?.0?1 O.C\1? . -..... ~ : • ..;7::: ·~..:;;~..., 1.424 2.255 1.983 0. 911 1996 0.454 1.'423 2.39 1 .963 0.907 1997 0.417 1.432 2.544 1.966 0.917 1998 0.37 1.456 2.721 1.956 0.946 1999 0.32 1.476 2.909 1.924 0.972 2000 0.26 -· -· REVGFR = Total State Government Revenues RP9SR = Petroleum Revenues RFDSR = Revenues from the Federal Government RNDSR = Other Revenues FUN DR = Real Fund Balance SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 157 TABLE 63. PROJECTED STATEWIDE REAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE E99SR -EXOGENOUS E99SRPC -EXOGENOUS t.1EAN MEAN 1980 o. 1980 o. 1981 o. 1981 0. 1982 o. 1982. o. 1983 1.462 1983 0.001 1984 3.449 1984 0.002 1985 7.507 1985 ·-0.002 1986 12.105 1986 -0.004 1987 29.753 1987 -0.001 1988 51.015 1988 o. 1989 .73.385 1989 -0.001 1990 .• 81.743 1990 0.001 1991 77.492 1991 -o .oo3 . 1992 72.783 1992 -0.003 1993 72:384 1993 -0.001 1994 74.95 1994 -o. ·---1:7:1-::J 7UoU~V 1995 -0.003 1996 80.771 . \ 1996 o • 1997 84.838 1997 0.002 1998 90.196 1998 -o. 1999 94.926 1999 -0.003. 2000 98.379 2000 0.002 E99SR = State Government Real Expenditures E99SRPC = Real Per Capita State Government Expenditures SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 158 [ [ [ c [ [ r L~ [ [ [ [ G [ L [ [ -.J -';! TABLE 64. PROJECTED STATEWIDE REAL GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE. '·' I I E99SR -EXOGENOUS E99SRPC -EXOGENOUS MEAN MEAN 1980 0. 1980 o. 1981 0. 1981 0. 1982 0. 1982 0. 1983 o. 1983 0.085 1984 0. 1984 0.192 1985 -o. 1985 0.391 1986 -o. 1986 0.593 ... 1587 1.382 1987 -o. .. 1988 0. 1988 2.247 1989 -o. 1989 3.058 1990 0. 1990. 3.221 1991 -o. 1991 2.883 1992 -o. . 1992 2.553 1993 -o. 1993 2.397 1994 -o. 1994 . 2,343 i9~5 -.;,;. ~ ;;~----~ ""o ...JVJ 1996 0. 1995 2.255 1997 o. 1997 2.238 1998 -o. 1998 2.248 1999 -o. 1999 2.235 2000 0. 2000 2.191 I E99SR = State Government Real Expenditures E99SRPC = Real Per Capita State Government Expenditures SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 159 Impacts of the Mean Case Scenario on the Anchorage, Southcentral, and Southwest Regions Regional Population Impacts Population impacts and percentage differences projected for the mean case for Southwest Alaska (POPTR2), Southcentral (POPTR4), and Anchorage (POPTR5) are presented in Tables 65 .and 66. In terms of the absolute impact, Anchorage undergoes the greatest expansion, with the difference between the mean case and base case growing from 3?5 people· in 1983 to 9184 people in 1990 (a 4.0 percent difference). After this peak percentage difference drops to about 2.6 percent by 2000. The impact on Southcentral and Southwest Alaska are similar in terms of the absolute level of population change. In both cases the population difference grows to about 1900 by the year 1990, and then declines moderately, but by the end of the projection period each has started to increase slightly. The percentage difference in the two regions differ because of the difference in the population base of the regions. In Southwest Alaska the peak level difference is about 5.6 percent and declines to about 2.1 percent. For Southcentral Alaska the percentage difference increases to 3.1 percent in 1990 and generally declines thereafter to 2.2 percent. It might also be noted that 75 percent of · the total population impact by the year 2000 is concentrated in the three regions. 160 r I ~· r L~ r L_ [ c [ r-; ~ [ [ ,- 1 L -, ., -' -, .__l, --, ~~-'· .J ., ·- '" ~ :..:; -~1 TABLE 65 PROJECTED REGIONAL POPULATION IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE ... I .., ! POPTR2 PO?TR4 POPTR5 1980 0. 0. o. 1981 0. o. 0. 1982 o. 0. o. 1983 -o.oos 0.081 0.365 1984 . 0.006 0.16 0.714 1985 0.065 0.292 1. 382 1986 0.173 0.421 1 .936 ,. 1987 0.371 •0.937 4.759 1988 1.173 1. 312 6.578 1989 1.873 1.843 s.a47 1990 1. 792 1.94 9.184 1991 1.75 1.724 8.12 1992 i .634 1 .593 7.522 1993 1.533 1.545 7.42 1994 1.493 1. 531 7.374 1995 1.467 1 • S3:l ·1. 3G2 1996 1.442 1 .541 7.363 1997 1.412 1.59 7.611 1998 1.395 1.655 7.937 1999 1.401 1.681 8.028 2000 1.4 1. 713 8.034 ;~ POPR2 = Total Population, Region 2 (Southwest) POPR4 = Total Population, Region 4 (Southcentral) POPR5 = Total Population, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 161 ' TABLE 66. PROJECTED REGIONAL POPULATION IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE ---·-·-----··-·-·--·--.. _ ----.---··-. ·-POPTR2 POPTR4 POPTRS 1980 0. o. 0. 1981 o. 0. 0. 1982 o. o. o. -1983 -0.029 0.167 0.19 1984. 0.021 0.307 0.346 1985 0.233 0.524 0.628 1986 0.582 0.7 0.858 1987 1.207 1.5 2.117 1988 3.689 2.103 2.922 1989 5.619 2.928 3.891 1990 5.008 3.056 3.964 1991 4.541 2.667 3.409 1992 3.933 2.429 3.069 1993 3."448 2.314 2.952 1994 3.079 2.294 2.87 l~::~i:> 2.935 2.269 2.794 1996 2.7 2.233 2.713 1997 2.503 2.242 2.714 1 S9B 2.327 2.278 2.743 1999 2.22 2.275 2.699 2000 2.122 2.211 2.623 POPR2 = Total Population, Region 2 (Southwest) POPR4 =Total Population, Region 4 (Southcentral) POPR5 = Total Population, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 162 r t ~-­ L [ ,. - i '-. r·· I L_ [ L [ r - I L [ I 1 j, _j _, .J Regional Employment Impacts The impact of the mean case is projected fqr each of the three regions for several categories of employment, including total employment (EM99), support sector employment (EMSl), basic sector employment (EMBl), and government sector employment (EMG9). For each of the employment variables there. is a strong cyclical pattern present ... that largely fol- 1 I lows project employment. In Region 2 total employment impact peaks in 1989, with an additional 962 employees (a 6.0 percent increase above the base case), with only a modest decline thereafter. The percentage difference drops to 2.3 percent by 2000. The peak differentials (absolute level and percentage differences) for Region 4 and Region 5 are, respectively; 1138 employees, 3.7 percent, and 5614 employees and 4.8 percent. For both regions the percentage difference declines steadily until the end of the projection period. About 78 percent of the total state employment impact in the peak year occurs in the three regions. (See Tables 67 and 68.) Differences in basic sector employment for the peak year (1989) are respectively 109, 467, and 1679 for Regions 2, 4, and 5. The comparable percentage differentials are 3.1 percent, 5.4 percent, and 13.3 percent. Thus, the largest percentage impacts occur outside the impacted region. This reflects two phenomena. First, nonresident enclave employment is not included in developing the projections. Second, the employment data reflect place of residence rather than the place of work. In the case 163 TABLE 67. PROJECTED REGIONAL TOTAL EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE ' EM99R2 EM99R4 EM99R5 1980 0. 0. 0. 1981 o. o. o. 1982 o. 0. 0. 1983 0.001 0.046 0.217 1984 0.01 0.094 0.45 1985 0.039 0.182 0.892 1986 0.087 0.262 1.24 1987 0.244 0.638 3.095 1988 0.622 0.861 4.312 1969 0.969 1. 12S 5.614 ;~~v 0.9'34 1 • 1 :Z4 S.S3S 1 Q91 0.899 0.89 4.455 1992 0.851 0.759 3.767 1993 0.82 0.701 3.541 1994 0.818 0.675 3.454 1995 0.815 0.662 3.412 1996 0.813 0.653 3.386 1997 0.814 0.673 3.524 1998 0.823 0.706 3.725 1999 0.836 0.713 3.778 2000 0.837 0.718 3.767 EM99R2 = Total Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EM99R4 =Total Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EM99R5 = Total Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 164 ~ [ \ .-· l~ [ [ r ~ I L~ [ r~ L. r~, t [ [ r~ .. u B [ [ r L f' I L [ 'I i• - -~ ....J c..i -, ·• _; ' .... <.4 TABLE 68. PROJECTED REGIONAL TOTAL EMPLOYMENT ··IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE .• ·-------·-.. EM99R2 EM99R4 EM99R5. 1980 o. o. 0. 1981 o. 0. o. 1982 o. 0. o. 1983 0.009 0.206 0.237 1934 0.077 0.373 0.444 1995 0.292 0.672 0.8Q1 1986 0.606 0.899 1. 073 1987 1. 641 2~ 137 2.683 1S38 4.029 2.869 3.737 1999 5.955 3.727 4.789 i ;;~ $.31S ~-592 4-.533 1991 4.712 2.754 3.543 1992 4.15 2.287 2.882 1993 3.655 2.048 2.617 1994 3.313 1 .• 963 2.479 1995 3.156 1.884 2.376 1996 ·2.908 1. 799 2.275 1997 2.721 1. 784 2.276 1998 2.558 1.809 2.317 1999 2.439 1. 793 2.274 2000 2.304 1. 705 2.193 EM99R2 = Total Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EM99R4 Total Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) = EM99R5 = Total Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 165 ' ·II, of Region 5 (Ahchorage) part of the expansion reflects project-related employment in Anchorage based headquarters. (See Tables 69 and 70.) For reference purposes Appendix D includes direct OCS employment by place of work as well as by place of residence. Support sector peak differences (in absolute and percentage terms) for the three regions are respectively; Region 2 (781, 20.6 percent), Region 4 (498, 4.6 percent), and Region 5 (3275, 5.6 percent). The relatively high support sector impact for Region 2 reflects the inclusion of OCS-related transportation employment. (See Tables 71 and 72.) Finally, government sector differences in employment at peak project level {again in absolute and percentage differences) for the three regions are: Region 2 (109, 1.2 percent), Region 4 (210, 2.5 percent), and Region 5 (520, 1.3 percent). In each region the peak level impacts decline _modestly, with the percentage impacts in Regions 2 and 5 de- clining to about 1 percent, while for Region 4 the difference drops to about 1.7 percent. The supporting data for absolute changes are contained in Tables j3, and for percentage impact levels in Table 74. Regional Personal Income Impacts The impact of the mean case on regional real personal income is relatively small. For the three regions the peak differences between the mean and base cases (in absolute and percentage terms) are: Region 2 (23.7 million dollars, 4.8 percent), Region 4 (61.1 million dollars, 6.8 percent), and 166 [ [ [ [ [ r L [ [j· L r· L [ ' _, =:i " "' ' -- _j --, :J --, =~ :.3 ' _. ; I• TABLE 69. PROJECTED REGIONAL BASIC SECTOR EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE ·EMB1R2 EM31 R4 EMB1R5 1980 o. o. 0. 1 OR1 o. 0. o. 1982 o. 0. 0. 1983 0.001 0.024 0.096 1984 0.003 0.043 0.166 1985 o.ooa 0.081 0.301 1986 o.oo5 0.094 0.325 1987 0.08 0.368 1 .258 1988 0.095 0.37 1.286 1939 0.109 0.467 1. 679 1990 0.103 0.401 1. 516 1991 0.079 0.231 0.975 1992 0.077 0.229 0.98 1993 . 0.077 0.237 1. 034 1994 0.08 0.222 1.006 1995 0.081 0.212 0.976 1996 0.085 0.203 0.947 1997 0.068 0.217 1.013 1998• 0.092 0.232 1.087 1999 0.096 0.223 1.033 2000 O.CS9 0.22 t.029 EMB1R2 Basic Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) = EMB1R4 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMB1R5 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 167 'I TABLE 70. PROJECTED REGIONAL BASIC SECTOR EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE EMBtR2 . EMB1R4 EMS1RS 1980 o. o. 0. 1981 n. 0. 0. 1982 o. 0. 0. 1983 0.045 0.422 1.016 1984 0.165 0.541 1. 561 1985 0.362 0.989 2.573 1966 0.218 1.113 2.709 1987 3.015 4.386 10.368 1988 3.132 4.296 10.412 1989 3.07 5.354 13.293 1990 2.372 4.446 11.657 1991 1.489 2.452 7.234 1992 ·1.264 . 2.354 6.985 1993 1 .044 2.358 7.062 1994 0.908 2.309 6.655 1995 0.864 2.156 6.213 1996 0.788 1.966 5.764 1997 0.73 1.995 5.893 1996 0.684 2.069 6.058 1999 0.648 2.021 5.706 2000 0.616 1.782 5.285 EMB1R2 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMB1R4 =Basic Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMB1R5 = Basic Sector Employment, Region 5 {Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 168 [ [ L [ [ [ [ L L [ ~' _ _j ' /• TABLE 71. PROJECTED REGIONAL SUPPORT SECTOR EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE . EMS1R2 EMS1R4 EMS1RS 1980 o. o. 0. 1981 0. o. 0. 1982 o. 0. 0. 1983 -0.001 0.019 0.102 1984 0.003 0.042 0.24 1985 0.024 0.082 0.51 1985 0.067 0.132 0.783 1987 0.151 0.232 1. 601 1988 0.486 0.39 2.602 1989 0.731 0.489 3.274 1990 0.7:31 0.498 3.275 .,. nn• ~-7t 2 0-'\-25 :2. 76't 1992 0.677 0.322 2.143 1993 0.655 0.277 1. 923 1994 0.652 0.267 1 .872 1995 0.646 0.264 1. 861 1996 0.64 0.264 1. 867 1997 0.636 0.268 1. 929 1998 0.639 0.279 2.034. 1999 0.645 0.289 2.096 2000 0.642 0.296 2.118 EMS'lR2 = Support Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMS1R4 =Support Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMS1R5 = Support Sector Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 169 TABLE 72. PROJECTED REGIONAL SUPPORT SECTOR El~PLOYMENT IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE EMS1R2 EMS1R4 EMStR5 1980 0. o. o. 1981 0. o. 0. 1982 o. o. o. 1983 -0.032 0.287 0.257 1964 0.105 0.559 0.497 1985' ·0.809 0.932 0.901 1 ~86( 1.984 1.322 1. 327 1987 '· 4.328 2.212 2.774 1988 13.513 3.789 4.559 1989 20.557 4.654 5.646 1990 17.497 4.637 5.425 ~ ,... ...... 13.S&O 3.9lO 4.3t9 I..,J.:J• 1992 13.352 2.809 3. 184 1993 11.754 2.332 2.725 1994 10.468 2.194 2.563 1995 9.864 2.118 2.456 1996 8.953 2.046 2.351 1997 8.26 . 1.984 2.305 1998 7.562 1.976 2.317 1999 7.151 1 .967 2.296 2000 6.66 1.922 2.229 EMS1R2 = Support Sector Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMSlR4 =Support Sector Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMSlR5 = Support Sector Employment, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 170 [ r L [ c c [ C' L [ -, ~ : ~ = ~ _. ' ~ ~ -, ::;j -, -~ ~ TABLE 73. PROJECTED REGIONAL GOVERNMENT EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE EMG9R2 EMG9R4 EMG9RS 1930 0. o. 0. 1981 0. o. 0. 1932 0. o. . 0. 19i33 0.001 0.002 0.006 1934 0.004 0.007 0.019 1985 0.008 0.015 0.036 10::113 I) J11 5 o.o?q 0. 071 . ' 198i 0.016 0.029 0. 071 1988 0.044 O.C83 0.208 1989 0.082 0.155 0.388 1990 0.102 . 0.196 0.488 1591 0.109 0.21 0.52 1992 0.098 0.189 0.47 1993 0.088 0.171 0.424 1994 0.088 0.171 0.421 1995 .0.088 0.172 0.423 1996 0.088 0.173 0.425 0.175 1997 0.09 0.431 1998 0.093 0.182 0.448 1999 0.096 0.189 0.463 2000 0.097 0.19 0.467 . EMG9R2 = Total Government Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMG9R4 = Total Government Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMG9R5 = Total Governll]ent Employment, Region 5 _(Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 171 ! I i TABLE 74. PROJECTED REGIONAL GOVERNMENT EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE EMG9R2 EMG9R4 EMG9R5 1980 . o. o; 0. 1981 ·. 0. o. 0. 1932 . o. o . a·. . 1963 0.018 0.034 0.018 1984 0.053 0. 11 0.055 1985 0.095 0.217 0.101 1 ?e'5 0 ·182. 0.402 0.195 1967 0.164 0.379 0. 19 1988 0.519 1.067 0.549 1969 0. 94~ . 1.94 1·. 01 1990 1.165 2.395 1.253 1991 1.218 2.491 1.315 1992 1.061 2.181 1 • 168 1993 0.958 1.918 1.036 1994 0.932 1.851 1.007 1995 0.922 1.814 0.996 1995 0.912 1. 782 0.985 1997 0.913 1. 763 0.985 1998 0.931 1.775 1.003 1999 0.943 1. 775 1.015 2000 0.936 1.747 1.007 EMG9R2 = Total Government Employment, Region 2 (Southwest) EMG9R4 =Total Government Employment, Region 4 (Southcentral) EMG9R5 = Total Government Employment, Region 5 ·(Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 172 [ f~ l [ [ c L [ [ r· L [ __ J __; --, --~ _ _j -, _j ..., ; J l _J __j --~ ::j . ~ J -, ...; '' j. TABLE 75. PROJECTED REGIONAL REAL PERSONAL INCOME IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES: MEAN CASE PIRR2 PIRR4' PIRRS 1980 o. 0. o. 1981 o. o. o. ! . l::.tl~ v. v. v. 1933 0.129 1.694 6.796 1.584 . ·0.556 4.298 16.234 1985 1.684 1 0.323 36.711 1986 2.558 13.565 46.562 1987 10.107 44. 106 137.956 1588 17.965 54.377 177.931 1989 23.659 61 • 123 215.235 1990 23.171 54.734 200.895. 1991 19.271 34.63 144.737 1992 16.941 27.851 122 •. 906 1993 16.348 27.183 121.957 1994 10.685 26.452 121.074. 1995 16.98 26.25 121 .219 1996 17.61 9 26.274 122. 191 1997. 18.185 2 7. 937 130.586 1998 19.06 29.991 140.687 . 1999 19.798 30.292' 143.332 2000 20.502 30.804 144.148 PIPR2 = Real Personal Income, Region 2 (Southwest) PIPR4 = Real Personal Income, Region 4 (Southcentral) PIPR5 = Real Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 173 TABLE 76. PROJECTED REGIONAL REAL PERSONAL INCOME IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE ' \. PIRR2 PIRR4 PIRR5 1980 o. 0. 0. 1981 o. o. o. i::Oo.;! ii. ,.. v. v. 1983 0.04 0.308 0,3 1984 ·o. 1s1 0.545 0.591 1985 0.433 1.144 1. 151 1986 0.602 1 .471 1. 428 1987 2.313 5.033 4.316 1988 3.907 6.172 5.507 "1989 4.776 6.7S6 6.455 1990 4.167 5.774 5.731 1991 3.126 3.458 3.905 1992 2.469 2.659 3.143 1993 2. t 41 2.486 2.97 1 gg.; 1. 93 2.437 2.836 1995 1.853 . 2.344 2.718 1996 1. 733 2.228 2.6 1997 1 .642 2.228 2.623 1998 1.552 2.291 2.686 . 1999 1.501 2.291 2.619 2000 1.435 2.188 2.514 PIPR2 = Real Personal Income, Region 2 (Southwest) PIPR4 =Real Personal Income, Region 4 (Southcentral) PIPR5 = Real Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 174 [ [ L [ L [ L u [ l f ., L r· I L [ Region 5 (215.2 million dollars, 6.5 percent). By the end of the pro,;, je~tion period the percentage differences have narrowed to about 1.4 percent- 2.5 percent. (See Tables 75 and 76.) Real per capita income impacts generally reflect those observed at the statewide level. Increases occur at the start of the project (1983) and continue for a few years. These increases are followed by a period of declining differences, and towards the end of the projection period the differences become negative (although by less than 1 percent). As in the statewide case this is due to the combined effects of increasing population and a shift in the composition of employment from relatively high paying industries to expanded service sector employment. The effect in Regions 4 and 5 is negligible, but for Region 2 the capita. income is about 146 dollars below the base case. Supporting data are contained in Tables 77 and 78. The Low (Exploration Only) Case Scenario: Statewide and Regional Impacts The impacts associated with the low case, as measured against the base case are virtually undetectable. Insignificant differences between the low and base cases occur during the four years in which exploration activity takes place. Even at the "peak" of the impact, the percentage differences and variables rarely exceed 0.2 percent, and in most cases is substantially less (usually less than 0.1 percent). The only exception tp this occurs in the net migration (MIGNET) variable. Even in this instance the absolute impact is less than 200 people. For reference 175 TABLE 77. PROJECTED REGIONAL REAL PER CAPITA INCOME IMPACTS, ABSOLUTE VALUES~ t~EAN CASE PIRPC~2 PIRPCR4 PIRPCR5 1980 o. 0. 0. 1961 o. o. 0. 1982 0. 0. o. 1983 8.215 15.945 12.953 1984 18.238 35.902 32.512 1985 26.016 99.902 75.363 1986 2.844 11 7. 336 81.664 1987 155.477 488.086 306.176 1988 30.375 562.73 360.434 1989 -118.633 535.277 361.902 "1990 -124.387 333.809 . 257.176 1991 -216.398. 11 9. 281 74.656 1992 -243.504 35.93 11.406 1993 -216.984 27.461 2.977 1994 -198.672 22.742 -5.555 1995 . -192.867 1 2. 156 -12.508 1996 -179.23 -0.871 -19.074 1997 -165.1 OS -2.488 -15.625 ·-1998 -155.18 2.418 -1o·.o12 1999 -147.074 2.848 . -14.316· 2000 -145.703 -4.047" -20.012 PIRPCR2 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 2 (Southwest) PIRPCR4 =Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 4 (Southcentral) PIRPCR5 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 176 [ [ [ ~~ L [ L [ L [ f. L L ; -~ ·-· . ..> .. ;.; TABLE 78. PROJECTED REGIONAL REAL PER CAPITA INCOME IMPACTS, PERCENTAGE DIFFERENCES: MEAN CASE .. .. ,--PIRPCR2 PIRPCR4 PIRPCRS 1980 0~ o. 0 • . 1981 . . o. 0 •. 0. 1982 0. o. . 0. 1983 . -0.07 0.141· 0.11 1984 0.139 0.237 0.244 1985 0.199 ·o.617 0.52 1986 0.02 0.765 0.565 1987 1.093 3.481 2.154 1988 0.21 3.984 2.511 1989 -0.798 3.729 2.467 1990 -o.a 2.638 1.7 1991 -1.353· 0.77 0.48 1992 -1 .456 0~225 0.071 1993 -1.263. 0.168 0.018 1994 -1. 114 0.14 -0.033 1995 -1.052 0.073 -0.074 1996 -0.942 -o. oos -0.11 1997 -0.841 -0.014 -0.0!:$~ .1998 -o. 751 0.013 -0.055 1999 -0.704 0.016 -0.078 2000 -0.673 -0.022 ~0.107 PIRPCR2 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 2 (Southwest) PIRPCR4 = Real Per Capita Personal Income, ·Region 4 (Southcentra1) PIRPCR5 Real Per Capita Personal Income, Region 5 (Anchorage) = SOURCE: MAP Model Projections. 177 purposes the supporting data have been included in Appendix A. Also included in Appendix D is OCS direct employment by place of work as well as by place of residence. Population The Mean Case Scenario: The Aleutian Islands Census Division Impacts Population impacts at the census division level tend to be substantial, both in terms of resident and total population. The impacts would be much greater (in percentage terms) if it were not for the already large population increase associated with projected fisheries expansion. Table 79 includes the base case and mean case population projections. Resident population (BPOPP) impact first occurs in 1983 and increases rapidly to a peak value of 2033 in 1989 (23.3 percent above.the base case value). In absolute value the mean minus base case difference then declines until 1991, and stabilizes at about 1560 for there- mainder of the projection period. However, the percentage difference drops steadily as population growth relateq to expanded fisheries activity grows. By .2000 the percentage difference is only 3.7 percent. Because of the high proportion of enclave employment, the total popula- tion impact is greater and peaks in 1987 at a level of 6807 (46.1 per- cent above the base case). After a short period of decline (as activity shifts from development to production) the total impact stabilizes at about 2700 for the remainder of the projection period. The percentage impact declines to 5.0 percent. 178 f' L L c [ [ "'"J t, .i .: L i J l1 :.,, .~ l.l ... J U .. J , , J U .... ,, "' .Ji L.. . .. J J ' J . ' J TABLE 79. PROJECTED CHANGES IN RESIDENT AND TOTAL POPULATION MEAN CASE, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: 1981-2000* Change in % Dif. Total % Dif. Year BPOPP Res. Po~. Mean-Base Res. Po~. BASPP TOCSP Mean-Base TOTPOP 1981 3777 0 0.0 3777 10595 0 0.0 10595 1982 4169 0 0.0 4169 11565 0 0.0 11565 1983 4239 39 0.9 4278 11659 518 4.4 12177 1984 4447 69 1. 6 4516 11888 872 7.3 12760 1985 5056 148 2.9 5204 13077 1737 13.3 14815 1986 5316 286 5.4 5602 1.3373 2922 21.8 16294 1987 6179 1032 16.7 7211 14774 6807 46.1 21581 --' 1988 7295 1565 21.5 '8860 16379 6467 39.5 22846 ""-J 1989 8712 2033 23.3 10745 18279 5892 32.2 24172 1.0 1990 10860 1852 17. 1 12712 20875 4217 20.2 25092 1991 13551 1596 11.8 15147 24370 2594 10.6 26964 1992 15092 1612 1 o. 7 16704 25780 2756 10.7 28537 1993 18934 1586 8.4 20520 30257 2914 9.6 33171 1994 22343 i559 7.0 23902 33876 2764 8.2 36639 1995 23423 1572 6.7 24995 34643 2654 7.7 37297 1996 27939 1499 5.4 29438 39206 2466 6.3 41672 1997 30961 1534 5.0 32495 42219 2678 6.3 44898 1998 34501 1556 4.5 36057 45456 2884 6.3 48340 1999 38199 1539 4.0 39738 49001 2744 5.6 51745 2000 41597 1527 3.7 43124 52040 2609 5.0 54649 TABLE NOTES *BPOPP = resident civilian population, base case. Change in resident population = change in resident population due to OCS activity. BASPP =, rresident population plus military and dependents plus enclave employment, base case. TOCSP = total OCS-related population. Nonresident OCS population impact is equal to TOSCP -change in resident popul~tion. TOTPOP = BASPP + TOCSP. SOURCE: SCIMP mean case and base case projections. 180 L [' r . [ r~ L [ ~~ L..i [ L § c [ r I L [ Employment Projected resident and nonresident employment impacts are summarized in Table· 80. Changes in total resident employment (bTE) include changes in support sector employment (bEMS), changes in state and local govern- ment (included in ~EMG), and-changes in exogenous construction and mining (bEMX). The total resident employment impact grows to a peak of 1133 in 1989 {25.8 percent above the base case), drops slightly~ and averages about 873 for the remainder of the projection period. The percentage dif- ference declines to 3.9 percent. Employment in the support sector follows the same general pattern, peaking at a value of 445 above the base case (a percentage difference of 33.9 percent), dropping slightly, and then slowing increasing over the rest of the period. The percentage difference declines to 4.5 percent. State and local government employment is only modestly impacted. The mean minus base case difference peaks at 64 (in 1989) and is 5.5 per- cent above the base case. The absolute and percentage differences decline steadily thereafter. The greatest impact in absolute and percentage terms occurs in con- struction and mining. The difference in employment grows to 624 in 1989. Because of the extremely small base case value of the variable, the percentage difference is 1850.0 percent. The difference stabilizes 181 TABLE 80. PROJECTED CHANGES IN RESIDENT AND NONRESIDENT EMPLOYMENT, MEAN CASE, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: 1981-2000* AEMS AEMG AHIA AEMX ATE AEMM AENCLV A TOTE Year !'!Q.:.. ! !'!Q.:.. ! !'!Q.:.. ! ~ ! ~ ! ~ ! !iQ_,_ % No. % 1981 0 0.0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0.0 1982 0 0.0 0 0.0 0 .0 0 0.0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0.0 __, 1983 25 4.8 0 0.0 0 0 1 11.1 26 1.3 0 0 479 15.8 505 6.8 OJ 1984 44 7.9 0 0.0 0 0 2 20.0 46 2.3 0 0 803 26.3 849 11.2 N 1985 93 14.0 0 0.0 0 0 19 58.3 112 4.8 0 0 1589 43.8 1701 20.0 1986 164 22.5 0 0.0 0 0 45 221.4 209 8.3 0 0 2636 71.9 2845 32.6 1987 387 44.5 7 0.8 0 0 149 727.8 543 18.4 0 0 5775 137.4 6319 65.3 1988 422 39.7 36 3,5 0 0 392 1533.3 850 23.7 0 0 4902 104.4 5753 53.3 1989 445 33.9 64 5.5 0 0 624 1850.0 1133 25.8 0 0 3859 74.5 4992 41.3 . 1990 341 20.9 52 3,9 0 0 561 1119.6 954 17.1 0 0 2365 42.0 3319 24.2 1991 253 11.8 45 2.9 0 0 540 743.8 838 11.8 0 0 998 15.5 1835 . 11.4 1992 272 11.0 42 2.6 0 0 540 566.7 854 10.4 0 0 1144 18.2 1998 11.7 1993 295 9.5 34 1.8 0 0 540 400.0 869 8.5 0 0 1328 19.2 2197 12.0 1994 296 7.9 27 1.3 0 0 540 283.0 863 7.0 0 0 1205 16.9 2068 9.4 1995 297 7.2 25 1.1 0 0 540 235.4 862 6.5 0 0 1082 15.8 1944 8.6 1996 298 6.2 20 0.8 0 0 540 170.0 858 5.6 0 0 967 14.1 1825 7.4 1997 323 5.8 15 0.6 0 0 540 123.1 878 5.1 0 0 1144 16.7 2023 7.6 1998 351 5.6 12 0.4 0 0 540 90.8 903 4.7 0 . 0 1328 20.2 2231 7.9 1999 352 5.0 9 0.3 0 0 540 63.1 901 4.2 0 0 1205 18.8 2106 6.9 2000 353 4.5 7 0.2 0 0 540 41.4 900 3.9 0 0 1082 17.9 1982 6.2 rJ 'I l .... ~ ~ J TABLE NOTES * . ~TE = Change in total resident employment and is the sum of changes in the support sector resident employment (~EMS), changes in state and local government (federal government employment is not changed) employment (.t:.EMG), changes in manufacturing employment (.t:.EMA), and changes in exogenous resident construction and mining employment, or resident OCS employment (~EMX). Changes in total regional employ- ment (~TOTE) equal the change in resident employment plus the change in enclave employment (~ENCLV). Percentage differences are the per- centage differences between the mean case and base case. SOURCE: SCIMP mean case and base case projections. 183 at 540 in 1991 and remains at that level for the remainder of the projection period. The percentage difference declines to 41.4 percent. The nonresident employment impact is captured by changes in enclave employment. The difference peaks at 57-7p in 1978 (137.4 percent above the base case) and declines to an average of about 1150. The percentage difference drops as well, and averages between 15 and 20 percent for 1990-2000. The combined resident and nonresident employment impact peaks at a value of 6219 in 1987 (65.3 percent above the base case). Obviously this is a substantial increase, and would be far greater if fisheries- related employment had not also been growing. In absolute terms the difference drops considerably in the production phase, and averages about 2000 for most of the 1990s. The percentage difference drops steadily to a level of 6.2 percent. The Low Case Scenario: The Aleutian Islands Census Division As was the case at the statewide and regional levels, the impact of the low scenario is negligible. Impacts are limited to a five-year period (1983-1987). Population and employment projections are contained in Tables 81 and 82. Resident population peaks in 1985, at a level of 30 over the base case (0.6_percent), while total popuiation increases 184 r· [ [ [ [ [ [ [ L' L [ C c [ § [ [ f' L ,- 1 L L ..... 00 (Jl L. ' "' "'''" L,, , Li, , . 1 l L"" .J L. 1-·••.J u,, L. ,,, J TABLE 81. PROJECTED CHANGES IN RESlDENT AND TOTAL POPULATION, LOW CASE, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: 1981-1988* Change in % Dif. Total Year BPOPP Res. Pop. L011-Base Res. Pop. BASPP 1981 3777 0 0.0 3777 10595 1982 4169 0 0.0 4169 11565 1983 4239 15 0.4 4254 11659 1984 4447 25 0.6 4472 11888 1985 5056 30 0.6 5086 13077 1986 5316 27 0.5 5343 13373 1987 6179 11 0.2 6190 14774 1988 7295 0 0.0 7295 16379 *see notes to Table 79. There are no impacts after 1987. SOURCE: SCIMP low case and base case projections. , J , .J % Dif. TOCSP Low-Base TOT POP 0 0.0 10595 0 0.0 11565 203 1.7 11862 317 2.7 12205 372 2.8 13449 319 2.4 13692 128 0.9 14903 0 0.0 . 16379 ...... co 0'\ TABLE 82. PROJECTED CHANGES IN RESIDENT AND NONRESIDEHT ENPLOYMENT, LOW CASE, ALEUTIAN ISLANDS CENSUS DIVISION: 1981-1988* AEMS AEMG AEMA AEMX _ill_ AEMM AENCLV A TOTE Year ~ ! ~ ! ~ ! ~ ! ~ % No. ! ~ ! ~ ! 1981 0 0,0 0 0 0 D 0 0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 .o 0.0 1982 0 0.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0.0 1983 10 1.9 0 0 0 0 0 0 10 0.5 0 0 188 6.2 198 2.6 1984 16 2.9 0 0 0 0 0 0 16 0.8 0 0 292 9.6 308 4.1 1985 19 2.9 0 0 0 0 0 0 19 0.8 0 0 342 9.4 361 4.3 1986 17 2.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 17 0.7 0 0 292 8.0 309 3.5 1987 7 0.8 0 0 0 0 0 0 7 0.2 0 0 117 2.8 124 1.3 1988 0 0.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0 0 0.0 0 0.0 * See explanatory notes to Table 80. SOURCE: SClMP low case and base case projections. . .. ~ ....... ·~ --·:··-...... -·~· .. ··. -···· ... ;···~-~· ··-··-~~. -····· .. . ,.,---.... L .. J c--J ,~,-.J r-< l _l _; by 372, a 2.8 percent increase. In both instances the differences disappear by 1988 when exploration activity has ceased. Employment impacts are even less. Resident employment increases by 19 over the base case in 1985 (a 0.8 percent difference). Total em- ployment increases by 361, reflecting the large enclave employment proportion. The percentage difference is 4.3 percent. By 1988 the differences in all variables are back to zero. \ 187 -~ d APPENDIX A COMPUTER PRINTOUT OF LOW CASE IMPACTS, STATEWIDE AND REGIONAL 189 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE ....... (o 0 PO?TST -EXOGENOUS 1980 1981 1982 1983 1994 1985 1996 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 19:32 1993 1994 19Yo 19913 1997 1 S98 1999 2000 LO\~ 0. 0. 0. 0.164 0.317 0.443 0.486 0.395 0.232 0.153 0.124 0. 11 0.102 0.095 0.091 0.0!3'/ 0.088 0.083 0.079 0.075 0.072 .~~t.~ ! r--1 i...;'' ...... J r--; l J r-l· r·----, j r-----, L j L. L .. SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE MIGNET -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 0. 1981 0. 1982 0. 1983 0.164 1984 0.148 1985 0.114 1986 0.027 1987 -0.107 1988 -0.174 1989 -0.084 1990 -0.03 1991 -0.013 1992 -0.007 1993 -o .oos 1994 -0.004 ~ ~S\!3 -0.0~3 1996 0.002 1997 -0.004 __, 1998 -0.003 ~ 1999 -0.004 __. 2000 -0.001 ILL~ .. : j L'''"-' .J ~ ... ' ' j L .. . L.. J ' ' .. " '. j SIMULATION OUTPUT NATI NC - 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1965 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1 991 1992 1993 1994 .. ,...,."~' IVJ<J 1996 1997 __. 1998 lO N 1999 2000 BY VARIABLE EXOGENOUS LO\~ o. o. 0. 0. 0.007 0.012 0.016 0.016 0.011 . 0.004 0.001 -o. -0.001 -0.001 -o . .oo 1 -" ""• .... ..,...,. -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 ,...._..., ~-• _ _j ~· I ,j \1,, ,J ·l, ".d L. ; J 1_ .• " J \L~, ,_,,.;._ J ,,,, "', _} L ... J L,, " ... J l,.' l : .J ,J "( .J . ' .J .J 'J J I ,:•"~'\ (~;. ~,~ ,. )' SIMULATION OUTPUT BY DSET LO\~ EM99ST EM98ST EMB1ST EMS1 ST EMG9ST 1980 o. o. 0. o. o. 1981 0. o. o. o. o. 1982 0. 0. 0. o. o. 1983 0.121 0.116 0.059 0.046 0. 0'11 1984 0.224 0.216 0.08 0.106 0.03 1985 0.301 0.291 0.095 0.152 0.045 1986 0.317 0.306 0.088 0.165 0.053 1987 0.233 0.225 0.061 0.11 9 0.045 1988 0.103 0. 1 0.001 0.066 0.027 1989 0.045 0.043 0.004 0.026 0.013 1990 0.026 0.026 0.003 0.014 0.009 1991 O.C2 0.02 0.002 0.01 0.008 1992 0.018 0.017 0.002 0.008 0.007 1993 0.017 0.016 0.002 0.008 0.007 1994 0.016 0.016 0.002 o.oo8 0.006 1 \:1\:lo IJ,Olt:i V.VlO \),VV~ v.uvo v.uvo 1996 0.017 0.016 0.002 0.008 0.006 1997 0.017 0.017 0.002 o.ooa 0.006 _, 1998 0.016 0.015 0.002 o.ooa 0.006 \.0 1999 0.015 0.015 0.002 0.007 0.006 w 2000 0.015 0.015 0.002 o.ooa 0.005 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE PIRST - 1980 19B1 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1 0<;15 1996 1997 1998 ....... 1999 1.0 ~ 2000 r--- L EXOGENOUS LmJ o. o. o. 3.84 6.961 9. 703 9.961 7.199 2.758 1 .352 0.918 0.773 0.762 0. 727 0.734 n 7 •:u:t 0.871 0.758 0.777 0.738 0.813 r--l \ ' -, -] r-.l ,.,J L .. l l': k ',,J l ' .. JI 'J SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE PIRPCST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 4.148 1984 4.395 1985 4.84 1986 4. 703 1&8i 2.664 1988 -1.398 1989 -1.875 1990 -1.93 1 991 -1 .863 . 1992 -1.687 1993 -1.566 1994 -1 • .41 ·~::.5 -·j .3~.; 1996 -1.152 1997 -1.23 ..... 1993 -1.105 ~ 1999 -i. 031 (J1 2000 -0.679 t,'l~ SIMULATION OUTPUT WSG9RST - 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1969 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 _. 1998 I.D 0'1 1999 2000 __ ...., ~""' 1 ' ~-~~~ ,-~ .. ~·•;."'~ BY VARIABLE EXOGENOUS LO\~ o. o. 0. 0.24 0.648 1. 01 1. 21 7 1.106 o. 748 0.457 0.383 0.364 0.357 0.354 0.355 0. 2o::e 0.381 0.388 0.38 0.389 0.401 t-"l ·I] ,_...., '. I L' .I l:. "' L ;, ) l .I I. l .. J .J SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WSS1RST-EXOGENOUS LmJ 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 0.905 1984 2.222 1985 3.19 1 9!36 3.372 1997 2.322 1988 1.29 1989 0.515 1990 0.272 1991 0.194 1992 0.171 1993 0.153 1994 0.151 1985 0.151 1996 0.159 1997 0.17 __, 1998 0.146 U) 1999 0.151 '-1 2000 0.16:2 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WSB1RST-EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 2.022 1964 2.664 1965 3. 706 1986 3.625 1987 2.522 1988 0.241 1989 0.135 1990. 0.106 1991 0.093 1992 0.09 1993 0.083 1994 0 •. 085 ·~;::~:.;, "-'•""I'.JL 1996 0.095 1997 0.092 _. 1998 0.079 ! 1.0 1999 0.089 co 2000 0.096 ,. J L t. l " L._ L:. J l ...... .J l :. J .,,) (, ".J .. J SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WRB1RST-EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 0. 1981 0. 1982 o. 1983 0.344 1984 -15.379 1985 -19.371 1986 -5.68 1987 3.52 1988 -O.G52 1989 -0.023 1990. 0.137 1991 0.156 1992 0.246 1S93· 0.164 1994 . 0 •. 188 ~ ~::: :. ~:! 1996 0.145 1997 0.078 ..... 1998 0.035 1.0 1999 0.145 1.0 2000 0.258 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WRG9RST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 0.023 1984 -0.344 1985 -0.859 1986 -0.996 1987 -0.256 1988 0.559. 1989 1.172 1 !?90 1.437 1991 1.559 1992 1.59 1993 1. 574 1994 1 .563 ~~~~ ~ .~:~ 1996 1.676 1997 1. 707 N 1998 1. 641 0 1999 1.754 0 2000 1.82 r1 ,....--,. ;------] . j l .. ,; \,. ;,,; .. t i.L., . J L :., ... ) \.., ''"'·" ! J l' :.J l. . j SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WRS1 RST -EXOGENOUS LOI~ 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 -0.039 1984 -1.719 1985 -3.484 1986 -2.742 1987 -1.984 1988 -0.805 1989 -0.34 1890 -o .146 1991 -0.113 1992 -0.039 1993 -0.074 1994 -0.082 1995 -0.09 1996 -0.102 1997 -0.09 N 1998 -0.141 0 1999 -0.055 ....... 2000 -0.027 SIMULATION RPI 1980 1961 1982 1983 1984 19B5 1986 1987 1988 Hl89 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 4,... rtr:' .;....,.., 1996 1997 N 1998 0 1999 N 2000 OUTPUT BY VARIABLE -EXOGENOUS LOW c. o. o. 0.043 0.097 0.108 0.101 0.13 0.201 0.272 0.312 0.341 0.369 0.398 0.43 ~-~= "! 0.5 0.538 0.582 0.627 0.675 I~ r-r--', L. j, ... ,..----, l 'J r--. L ·~-. .---. . J I,U l IIIli.' '"' ''""' \_, "' " ,. Icc ,J I.!.,' .) ~ L ...... ,) t ... J. '" J u. ' J '.J l' 'J .,.lJ '" r~ r~:~ SIMULATION OUTPUT BY DSET LOW REVGFR RP9SR RFOSR RNDSR 1980 o. o. a. o. 1 981 0. o. o. o. 1982 o. 0. 0. o. 1983 -0.294 -0.285 .. 0.029 -0.039 1984 -0.586 -0.6 0.049 -0.037 1985 -0.559' -0.683 0 .. 074 0.053 1986 -0.418 -0.623 0.082 0.123 1997 -o. 723 -o. 753 0.051 -0.021 1988 -1 .484 ~ 1. 085 0.003 -0.402 1989 -2.262 -1.378 -0.022 -0.863 1990 -2.594 -1.399. -0.03 -1.167 1991 -2.762 -1.357 .-0. 031 -1.376 . 1992 -2.809 -1.233 ·. -0.031 -1.543 1993 -2.84S -1. 12 -0.031 -1.694 1994 -2.859 -0.999 -0.03 -1 .83 1Q~5 -!:! .. e;s -o. es-1 -0.0?9 -1.(l5"i 1996 -2.879 -o. 796 -0.028 -2.056 1997 -2.887 -0.711 -o. 021 -2.15 N 1998 -2.902 -0.635 -0.026 -2.24 0 w 1999 -2.902 -0.563 -0.026 ' -2.315 2000 -2.902 -0.498 -0.025 -2.379 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE E99SR -EXOGENOUS 1960 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 '1993 1994 1995 1996 '1997 N 1998 -~ 1999 2000 r---. \, . o. o. o. 0.666 1 .252 1. 763 2.005 1. 701 1. 04 5 0.717 0.594 0.546 0.516 0.502 0.496 0.469 0.517 0.5 0.471 0.477 0.461 ~\ (""'"T:i ~...... ... ~· .• I J \. II~~~ L .. L' . l_j ..:., .. 11..1 u .. ' ) ~~' !.,, _J L .. •· .. J Li ' J ' ) . J SIMULATiON OUTPUT BY VARIABLE E99SRPC -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 0.001 1984 -0.002 1985 -0.005 1986 0.001 1987 -0.001 1988 -0.001 1989 -0.001 1990 -0.004 1991 -0.002 1992 -0.005 1993 -o. oo 3 1994 -0.001 ~ c~= -~ .. ~~:! 1996 o. 1997 0.002 N 1998 -0.007 C> 1999 o. U1 2000 -0.005 SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE N 0 m FUNDR -EXOGENOUS 1980 1 981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1 991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 r---: I. LOW o. o. o. -1 .262 -3.363 -5.145 -6.48 -8.52 -11.613 -14.965 -17.437 -19.555 -21 • .0::69 -23.273 -24.914 -26.422 -27.832 -29.137 -30.379 -31.516 -32.492 1,.....,--, \.. l _j '> I ; .) .... -.. . ·:.,:;. SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE POPTST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1 981 o. 1982 0. '1983 0.039 198·1 0.07 1985 0.092 1986 0.098 '1987 0.079 1988 0 .04G 1989 0.03 1990 0.024 1991 0.02 1992 0.018 1993 0.017 1994 0.016 ~ ~~= ') 0~'5 1996 0.01•1 1997 0.013 N 1998 0.012 0 1999 0. 011 '-J 2000 0.011 Percentage ,(-Mit' SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE MIGN E1r -EXOGENOUS LO\~ 1960 o. 1981 0. 1982 o. 1983 1 .903 1984 0.569 1985 0.565' 1986 0.402 1987 3.545 1968 4.133 1989 8.029 1990 -0.503 1991 -0.153 . 1992 -0.1 1993 -0.073 1994 -0.093 ~ :::: -~-~:: 1996 0.018 1997 -0.038 1998 -0.033 N 1999 -0.046 0 00 2000 -0.012 Percentage r-r-'"!; l. ; ; ..........--, l [.-J .11~9~j "' L l ul J lL,, ,; l,..,. ' ,,) u", I J .) ,J ,J . J •. J "''i,~,·· r: ,. ' ·i SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIASLE NATINC-EXOGENOUS LOl~ 1980 o. 1981 0. 1982 0. 1983 o. 1984 0.153 '1985 0.23 '1966 0.271 1987 0.271 1988 0.197 1989 0.073 1990 0.013 1991 -0.008 1992 -0.016 1993 -0.018 1994 -0.019 1 ~195 -O.U1d 1996 -0.016 1997 -o. o 11 N 1998 -0.01 0 1.0 1999 -o.oos 2000 -0.007 Percentage ;-'"""\ . 4J~.· ,.~ ('~!)! <? (_. SIMULATION OUTPUT BY DSET LOW EM99ST EM98ST EMB1ST EMS 1ST EMG9ST 1980 o. o. o. o. o. 1981 0. 0. o. o. o. 1982 o. o. o. o. 0. 1983 0.059 0.06 0.156 0.065 0.014 1984 0.096 0. 1 0.165 0.125 0.036 1965 0.122 0.126 0.198 0.153 0.053 1986 0.125 0.13 0.199 0.158 0.06 1967 0.092 0.095 0.142 0.11 5 0.05 1988 0.041 0.042 0.016 0.064 0.03 1969 0.017 0.018 o.oo8 o;025 0,014 1990 0.01 0.01 0.005 0.013 0.01 1991 0.007 0.008 0.004 0.009 0.008 1992 0.006 0.006 0.003 0.007 0.007 1993 O.OOG 0.006 0.003 0.006 0.007 1994 0.005 0.005 0.003 0.006 0.006 1 '.?95 n,nn':i n noc:; 0 003 0.006 0.00() 1996 0.005 0.005 0.003 0.006 0. 00(., 1997 0.005 0.005 0.003 0.006 0.001· N 1998 0.004 0.005 0.003 o.o·o5 0.00!· __, 1999 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.005 0.005 0 2000 0.004 0.004 0,002 0.004 0.005 Percentage -_ ... -..... , ..... ''-:"""· ......... ~ ......... -....... -· .............. ·· ~-... -~ r--1 •• ,_.j .:--J "' ' J ;,.. ' I ,J Lt.:. ,J .J u ,j SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE PlRST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 0. 1982 o. 1983 0.071 1984 0.098 1985 0.121 1986 0.128 1987 0.097 1988 0.037 1989 0.018 1990. 0. 011 1991 0.009 . 1992 o.oos 1993. o.oo8 1994 . 0.007 1Z~5 "' f't,...., "'•"'""'. 1996 0.008 1997 0.006 N 1998 0.006 ..... 1999 0.006 __, :2000 0.006 Percentage ..... , ··;: {~~ .f::/f_:.~~ A'"'~ _., !' . ',,.,··: SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE PIRPCST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 0.033 1984 0.028 1985 0.029 1966 0.03 1987 0.018 1988 -0.009 1989 -0.012 1990 -0.012 1991 -0.012 1992 -0.01 1993 -0.009 1994 -0.008 , \:1\:l::i -v.vuil 1996 -0.006 1997 -0.007 N 1998 -0.006 __, 1S99 -0.005 N 2000 -0.004 Percentage h..' ,J L ',J b_,[ ,,,, ,; L ,, .I ,, SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIA'SLE N __, w WSG9RST -EXOGENOUS 1 SGO 1981 1982 1983 1964 ' 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 L0\•1 o. o. o. 0.014 0.035 0.05 0.056 0.049 0.032 0.019 0.015 0.014 0.013 0.012 0.012 0. 011 0. 011 0. 011 0.01 0.01 0.01 Percentage l,,,' .. J L. ,,, J L,,', ,j ,J ' j ,J ,~·mo... f1.71~ ~1-f~~(~."! ") I ~ ··1 (-:_), SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE \>1551 RST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 0. 1982 0. 1983 0.065 1984 0.11 7 1985 0.138 1966 0.146 1987 0.1 CG 1988 0.06 1989 0.024 1990. 0.012 1991 0.008 1992 0.007 1993 0.006 1994 . 0.005 a ;s;:; Vo~Vj 1996 0.005 1997 0.005 N 1998 0.004 ~ 1999 0.004 ~ 2000 0.004 Percentage t , L' ,. '"" .} '~ ' '' L I "' J ' ,, ,j SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WSB1RST-EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1 961 0. 1982 o. 1963 0.157 1964 0.131 1985 0.156 1966 0.166 198'7 0. 151 1968 0.014 1869 o.ooa 1990 0.006 1 991 0.004 1992 0.004 1993 0.004 1994 0.004 1 ::!:?:: 0 -~~3 1996 0.004 1997 0.003 N 1996 0;003 U1 1999 0.003 2000 0.003 Percentage SIMULATION OUTPUT 13Y VARIABLE \oJRB1 HST -EXOGENOUS L0\<1 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 0.001 1984 -0.034 1985 -0.039 1986 -0.013 1987 J.009 1988 -0.002 1989 -o. 1990 o. 1991 o. 1992 0.001 1993 o. 1994 o. 191?B 0. 1996 o. 1997 o. N 1998 o. ..... 1999 o. 0) 2000 0.001 Percentage ~I ~: ,~..., l. i ) 1 ,--, : _I ~~ ' I - ,' r·-, I (.: (.> ,j t .. L, ,I L. ,, .I L , J lt .... J L. i, .J l... ' j ' J L..' ..J l .J j 'j SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE WRG9RST -EXOGENOUS LO\~ 1980 o. 1981 0. 1982 0. 1983 0. 1984 -0.002 1965 -0.004 1986 -0.004 1987 -0.001 1988 0.002 1989 0.004 1990 o. 005 1991 0.006 1992 0.006 1993 0.005 1994 0 .oos 1 \:1\:Jo u.uu::> 1996 o.oos 1997 0.005 N 1998 0.005 __, 19S9 0.005 "'-..I 2000 o.oos Percentage SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE \<IRS1 RST -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 -o. 1984 -0.008 1965 -0.015. 1986 -0.012 1987 -o .oc9 1988 -0.004 1989 -0.002 1990 -o.oot 1991 -0.001 . 1992 -o • 1993 -o. 1994 -o .. ~ ;;::; ~ "\I-• 1996 -o. 1997 -o. N 1998 -0.001 ...... 1999 -o. 00 2000 -o. Percentage -: l L J L , L ... J L I ,_,J L. . i l. . J : j : .. J .. J :J SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE RPI -EXOGENOUS LO\~ 1980 o·. 1981 o. 1962 o. 1983 0.009 1984 0.02 1985 0.02 1986 0.018 1967 0.021 1988 0.03 1989 0.038 1990. 0.04 1991 0.041 . 1992 0.041 1993. 0.041 1994 . 0.042 i~;o V.U-1.2 1996 0.042 1997 0.042 N 1998 0.042 __, 1999 0.042· ID 2000 0.042 Percentage SIMULATION OUTPUT BY DSET LOW RE VGFR 1980 0. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 -0.008 1984 -0.014 1985 -0.012 1986 -o .oo8 1987 -0.014 1988 -0.027 1989 -0.039 1990 -0.045 1991 -0.047 1992 -0.049 1 S93 -0.05 1994 -0.052 1995 -0.054 1996 -0.055 1997 -0.057 N 1998 -0.058 N 1999 -0.06 0 2000 -0.061 RP9SR RFDSR 0. o. o. o. o. o. -0.009 0.016 -0.02 0.028 -o. 02 0.043 -0.018 0.05 -o. 021 0.034 -o .o3 0.002 -0.038 -o. 011 -0.04 -0.024 -o. 041 -0.027 -o. o41 -0.028 -o .041 -0.029 -0.042 -0.03 -o. 042 -0.031 -0.042 -0.031 -0.042 -0.032 -0.042 -0.033 -0.04.2 -0.033 -0.042 -0.034 Percentage RNDSR o. o. o. -0.007 -0.004 0.005 0.009 -0.001 -o. 02 3 -0.043 -0.053 -0.056 -0.058 -0.06 -0.061 -0.063 -0.064 -0.065 -0.067 -0.068 -0.069 r-l l J "j LJ,.:, u.. J ll j L. , , J I J L.. , J .J ' J I . ., SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE E99SR -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1961 0. 1982 o. 1983 0.039 1984 0.07 1985 0.092 1986 0.098 1987 0.079 1988 0.046 '989 0.03 1990 0.023 1991 0.02 1992 0.018 1993 0.017 1994 0.016 ~ s~::: 0 .. ~~.., "1996 0.014 1997 0.013 N 1998 0.012 N 1999 0. 011 ........ 2000 0.01 Percentage /~. r SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE E99S RPC -EXOGENOUS Lml 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 0. 1983 o. 1984 -o. 1985 -o. 1986 o. 1 S87 -o. 1988 -o. 1S89 -o. 1990 -o. 1991 -o. 1992 -o. 1993 -o. 1994 -o, "---I':):;J,J .. v .. 1996 o. 1997 o. N 1998 -o. N N 1999 o. 2000 -o. Percentage f'~'' r:n ·.~ ' j •. J L ,) ' . .; .. J \,,.,, L .. J l .. ! j L • !.J .J .J . J ~~ SIMULATION OUTPUT BY VARIABLE FUNOR -EXOGENOUS LOW 1980 o. 1981 o. 1982 o. 1983 -0.017 1984 -o .036 1985 -0.044 1986 -0.045 1987 -0.051 1988 -0.061 1999 -0.069 1990 ':"'0.073 1991 -0.076 1992 -0.078 1993 -0.081 1994 -0.084 1 ~<::: -0 f'IClq 1996 -0.092 1997 -Cl.097 N 'I 998 -0.103 N 1999 -0.109 w 2000 -0.117 Percentage .f~.j);h., tWr.~: AI·"F\ I ' ' SIMULATION OUTPUT BY OSET -ERROR RRE7 095_ER POPTR2 POPTR4 POPTR5 1980 0. o. o. 1 981 o. o. 0. 1982 o. o. o. 1983 -0.004 0.038 0. 171 1984 o. 0.065 0.273 1985 0.004 0.084 0.36 1986 0.007 0.085 0.365 1987 0.012 0.057 . 0.256 1988 0.013 . 0.024 0.113 1989 0.009 0.015 0.079 1990 0.007 0.012. 0.063 1 991 0.007 0.011 0.055 . 1992 0.007 0.01 0.05 1993 0.007 0.01 0.046 199·~ 0.007 0.009 0.043 .,.._ ... .... ,..,... ~ ,.. ,.,.,n ~. ~~~ I :.F;J..J v.v.,;v vevv.., 1996 0.007 0.009 0.041 1997 0.006 0.008 0.039 N 1998 0.006 0.008 0.037 N 1999 0.006 0.007 0.035· .f.:> 2000 0.006 0.007 0.034 EM99R2 EM99R4 EM99R5 1980 0. o •. o. 1981 0. o. o. 1982 0. o. 0. 1983 0. 0.021 0. 1 1984 0.003 0.036 0.168 1985 0.004 0.048 0.221 1986 0.005 0.049 0.221 1987 0.006 0.032 0.147 1988 0.004 0. 011 0.05 1989 0.002 0.005 0.022 1\:190 0.001 U.OU.:l U.Vl.:l 1991 0.001 0.002 0.01 1992 0.001 0.002 0.008 1993 0.001 0.002 0.008 1994 0.001 0.002 0.008 1995 0.001 0.001 o.oo8 1996 0.001 0.002 o.ooa 1997 0.001 0.002 0.008 1998 o. 0.001 0.008 1999 o. 0.001 0.008 2000 o. 0.001 o.oo8 EMS! R2 EMS1 R4 EM$1R5 1980 o. o. .0. 1981 o. o. 0. l'J 1"'""...3~82 r-; ~oo 1 r-'J g:o~r 1. .. 1 1 )4......., r:-J ~ r-1 rl. ::-J ~J .~ :-l ~ :-"-l ~--:1 ~ l . _J33 L ... J .J >d L, ' I ,J ' J L . .J L ... !, .. :.J t:., l : ... ..J l.. . ... j l. I. J IJ ..J ~. .J 1985,p~ 0.001 0.022 0.122 ,..'11;,: fJ'f;~ 1986; .. 0.001 0.023 0.126 1967 0.002 0.013 0. 081 1968 0.002 0.006 0.037 1989 0.001 0.002 0.015 1990 o. .. 0.001 0.008 ~ ;; i ,J. ... ""'~"' "" ............. V•lrJ'-'1 v.vvv 1992 0. 0. 0.005 1993 0. o. 0.005 1994 o. o. 0.005 1995 o. 0. 0.005 1996 o. o. 0.005 1997 o. o. 0.005 1998 o. o. 0.005 1999 -o. o. 0.005 2000 . -o. o. 0.005 EMG9R2 EMG9R4 EMG9R5 1980 o. o. o. 1 981 o. 0. o. 1982 o. o. 0. 1983 0.001 0.001 0.004 1984 0.002 0.004 0. 01 1985 0.003 0.006 0.015 1986 0.004 0.007 0.017 1987 0.003 0.006 0.015 19138 0.002 0.004 0.009 N 1989 0.001 0.002 0.004 N 1990 0.001 0.001 0.003 01 1 991 o. 0.001 0.002 1992 0. 0. 001 0.002 1993 0. 0.001 0.002 1994 o. 0.001 0.002 1995 o. 0.001 0.002 1996 0. 0.001 0.002 1997 o. 0.001 0.002 1998 o. 0.001 0.002 1999 o. 0.001 0.002 2000 o. 0.001 0.001 EMB1R2 EMB1 R4 EMB1R5 1980 o. o. o. 1 ~tn u. v. o. 1982 o. o. o. 1983 -o. 0.012 0.048 1984 o. 0.016 0.063 1985 o. 0.018 0.074 1986 o. 0.018 0.067 1987 0. 0.012 0.045 1988 o. 0.001 0.003 1989 0. o. 0.001 1990 0. o. 0.001 1991 o. o. 0.001 1992 o. o. 0. 001 1993 o. a. 0.001 1994 o. o. 0.001 1995 o. o. 0.001 1996 0. o. 0.001 1997 0. o. 0.001 1998 o. o. 0.001 1 qqq 0. D •. 0.001 ,,:%~ ~~:J!:;"A..~. f?:r\ PIRR2 PIRR4 PIRR5 1980 0. 0. o. 1 981 0. o. o. ....... ,...,.., ~ ~. ~. •.J-.J'-.... 1983 0.024 0.685 2.973 1984 0.094 1.209 5.333 1985 0.141 1 .682 7.371 1986 0.169 1 .664 6.965 1987 0.192 1. 079 4.431 ' 1988 0. 141 0.292 1. 226 1989 0.07 0.129 0.625 1990 0.046 0.079 0.441 1991 0.038 0.06 0.386 1992 0.036 0.058 0.381 1993 0.034 0.053 0.371 1994 0.032 0.053 0.371 1995 0.029 0.054 0.379 1£96 0.04 0.067 0.441 1997 0.028 0.053 0.395 '1998 0.027 0.053 0.402 '1999 0.02 0.05 0.395 2000 0.029 0.056 0.426 PIRPCR2 PIRPCR4 PIRPCRS N 1960 o. o. o. N 1981 o. o. o. (J) 1982 o. 0. o. 1983 2.836 5.23 4.977 1984 3.375 4.43 8.207 1985 3.156 5.672 9.746 1986 2.191 5.98 7.461 1987 o. 723 4.43 3.535 1988 -1.527 -0.824 -1.762 1889 -1 .832 -1.449 -2.32 1990 -1.~49 -1.641 -2.23 1991 -1.91 -1.695 -1.996 1992 -1 .883 -1.633 -1.711 1993 -1 .816 -1.586 -1.523 1994 -1.766 -1.445 -1.328 1995 -1.766 -1.344 -1.191 1996 -1.648 -1. 199 -0.988 1 0~7 -1 70"1 -1. ::!?4 -1 .oss 1998 -1.594 -1 • 187 -0.906 .' 1999 -1.559 -1.09 -0.852 2000 -1.375 -0.93 -0.719 ~I ,,..-----., . .. I L, .I :l SIMULATION OUTPUT BY DSET -PERCENT ERROR N N '-I RRE7 095_PC ER 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 . 1992 1993 1994 ~ ::s 1996 1997 '1998 1999 2000 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1 ~~u .1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 1980 1981 1982 1983 POPTR2 0. 0. 0. -0.016 0.002 0.014' 0.025 0.039 0.041 0.026 0.021 0.018 0.016 0.015 0.014 :::. ~ ~ :! 0.012 0. 011 0.01 0.009 0.008 EM99R2 o. o. 0. 0.001 0.02 0.03 0.036 0.038 0.027 0. 011 u.vvo 0.004 0.003 0.003 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.001 EMS1 R2 o. o. o. -0.021 POPTR4 POPTRS o. o. 0. 0. 0. 0. 0.078 0.089 0.124 0.133 0.151 0 •. 164 0.141 0.162 0.092 . 0. 114 . 0.039 0,05 0.024 0.035 0.019 .. 0.027 0.017 0.023 0. 016 ·. 0.02 0.015 0.018 0.014 0.017 ~.C1~ n n1c:: .... ·.,; .... 0.013 0.015 0.012 0.014 0. 011-0.013 0.01 0.012 0.009 0.011 EM99R4 EM99R5 o. 0. o. 0. 0. 0. 0.094 0. 109 0.144 0.166 0' 176 0.199 0.167 0. 191 0.107 0.127 0.038 0.043 0.015 0.018 v.vil9 u.vi 0.006 0.008 0.005 0.006 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.003 0.005 0.003 0.005 0.003 0.005 EMS1 R4 EMS1RS o. o. o. o. o. o. 0. 114 0.108 u : ... J l" ,, "' ~. ' I. J . J .. J J 1985 ...,.,..~ 0.028 0.252 0.216 ~..,,1 tf'"'"'· 1986 ', 0.039 0.229 0.213 ~ U,o;~~ 1987 0.063 0.122 0.14 1988 0.055 0.06 0.064 1969 0.02 0.022 0.026 1990 ' 0.008 0. 01 0.013 iS~i v.vv.; ~ ,.. .... ,.., ... ,.._ ... V•\JVV .\/oVVWI 1992 0.002 0.004 0.007 1993 0.002 0.003 0.007 1994 0.001 0.003 0.006 1995 0.001 0.003 0,006 1996 0.001 0.003 0,006 1997 0.001 0.003 0.006 1998 o. 0.003 0.006 1999 -o. 0.002' 0.005 2000 -o. 0.002 0.005 EMG9R2 EMG9R4 EMG9RS 1980 0. o. o. 1981 0. o. o. 1982 0. o. 0. 1983 0.01 0.021 0. 011 1984 0.026 0.06 0.028 1985 0.038 0.068 0.041 1986 0.044 0.096 0.047 1987 0.037 0.079 0.039 1988 0.022 0,047 0.023 N 1989 0.01 0.023 0.011 N 1990 0.007 0.016 0.007 co 1991 o.oos 0.014 0.006 1992 0.005 0.013 0.005 1993 0.004 0.012 0.005 1994 0.004 0.011 0.004 1995 0.004 0.01 0.004 1996 0.004 0.01 0.004 1997 0.004 0.01 0.004 1998 0.004 0.009 0.004 1999 0.003 o.oo8 0.004 2000 0.003 o.ooa 0.003 EMB1 R2 EMB1R4 EMBtRS 1980 0. o. o. i \:ll::l 1 v. ii. o. 1982 o. 9. o. 1983 -o. 0.206 0.502 1984 0.01 0.197 0.589 1985 0.015 0.224 0. 631 1986 0.016 0.208 0.561 1987 0.016 0.147 0.368 1988 0.013 0.012 0.021 1989 0.006 0.005 0.012 1990 0.004 0.003 0.009 1991 0.002 0.002 0.007 1992 0.002 c .·<.01 0.007 1993 0.001 0.001 0.007 1994 0.001 0.001 0.007 1995 0.001 0. 001 0.007 1996 0.001 0.001 0.007 1997 0.001 0.001 0.006 1...2.,98 r~ o. r-J~:~~ ').006 [-:; ;--r. r-"J r-"" r-_)99 rn CL 1 ,, '} r-l .~ :-------1 ,----. ~ . r-----: ~. r-l 1.. } I. .,.J L l,j l. ' I ,J L,J,,J,j u,., J ~ L ~. J L .. , ,.J ,. J L J L .. ,IJ l,.i.' .J .J ' .J .J J ~~~ .... If'#~: ~~~~~. PI RR2 PIRR4 PIRR5 1980 o. o. 0. 1981 o. o. o. ... 1:,10"" v. Vo ..,. 1983 0.008 0.125 0. 131 1984 0.027 0.153 0.194 1985 0.036 0.186 0.231 1986 0.04 0.18 0.214 1987 0.044 0.123 0.139 1988 0.031 0.033 0.038 1989 0.014 0.014 0.019 1990 o .ooa 0.008 0.013 1991 0.006 0.006 0.01 1992 0.005 0.006 0.01 1993 0.004 0.005 0.009 1994 0.004 0.005 0.009 1995 0.003 0.005 o.ooa 1996 0.004 0.006 0.009 1997 0.002 0.004 0.008 1998 0.002 0.004 0.008 '1999 0.002 0.004 0.007 2000 0.002 0.004 0.007 PI R PCR2 PIRPCR4 PIRPCR5 N 1980 o. o. o. N 1981 0. o. 0. \0 1982 o. 0. o. 1983 0.024 0.046 0.042 1984 0.026 0.029 0.062 1985 0.022 0.035 0.067 1986 0.015 0.039 0.052 1987 0.005 0.032 0.025 1988 -o. o 11 -o .oo6 -0.012 1989 -0.012 -0.01 -0.016 1990 -0.013 -0.011 -0.015 1991 -0.012 -0.011 -0.013 1992 -o. o 11 -0.01 -0.011 1993 -o. 011 -0.01 -0.009 1994 -0.01 -0.009 '-0.008 1 ~95 -0.01 -0.008 -0.007 1 96 -0.009 -o. 001 -0.006 ~ 997 -0.009 -n (1()7 -n onn 1998 -o.oos -0.007 -0.005 1999 -0.007 -0.006 -0.005 2000 -o .oos -0.005 -0.004 _ _; - ~ -"' APPENDIX B FISHERIES ASSUMPTIONS 231 . ' . EARL R. COMBS, INC . ~------------· CONSUlJANTS IN ECONOMICS AND PL.ANI':JING-----------1 ,. \ 9725-S.£. 36th St. • Mercer Island. WA 98040 • (206)232-3991 TO: Roger Harks BLH/OCS Office PO Box 1159 Anchorage AK 99510 MEMORAl~DUH 7/17/80 Coc~e~ts Re~arding Technical Mepos. SG-3 and BF (71-1) Based upon a review of the nethods, standards and assunptions applicable to Technical Memo SG-3, I have several conments regarding some of the assumptions which will be utilized for the ISER model. It ~s my opinion that the employnent assumptions as they exist right now are not reflect~ve of the industrial character of fishing activity which is likely ~o take place in the future. At the present time, as well as historically, the nature o£ ~laskan fisheries is one of utilizating hig~ value resources on a seasonal basis by employing mostly transient labor. A significant number of fishing vessels are used which spend a large amount of time berthed in locations far from the fishing grounds; in some cases outside of the State of Alaska. This is pa~ti6ularly true about the areas for both the st. George and Northe~n Aleutian lease sales impacts studies. Fisheries in this part of-Alaska are predominantly for king and tanner crab, salmon, halibut and shrimp. The k~ng and tanner crab fisheries are largely based at Dutch Harbor during the season with some vessels basing at Kodiak and to a lesser desree at other ports along the Alaska Peninsula. Vessels spend from two, to at most six, months in these fishe~ies. The sal~on fishery relies heavily on drift gillnet vessels that operate out of several ports in Bristol Bay. These are coastal fisheries. Again, the season is short and the activity peaks during a small part of the year. Halibut fishing is accomplished primarily by traditional ·halibut schooners nany of which base themselves in Puget Sound and travel to Western Alaska for the prime fishing seasons. It is a short season because of quota restrictions~ Shrimp trawling is acconplished primarily by the drag fleet centered in Kodiak. Again, these vessels currently participate in that fishery d ur:,ing only a portion of the year. Processing activities for all of these fisheries are geared to the fishing seasons. Most of the products are packed or canned during the limited season. Both the 232 [ [ [~: [ [ r~ L [ [ ~~ I L L-----------------------------------------------------------~- ' .... ECi ··: .J - .J _j Roger Harks Continued -2- harvesting and processing labor forces are ~ade up largely of people who do not live at the locations froo which they base their fishing or conduct their processing. The largest opportunities for expanding U.S. coo~ercial fisheries in the future lie in the cooplex of fishes coomonly referred to as bottomfish. These resources are abundant in the Bering Sea and currently support a large distant water fishery prosecuted by foreign flee~s al~ost exclusively. There is a small level of bottoofish.fishing by the shriDp drag fleet out of Kodiak. This currently accounts for less than 1% of the total production. Most of the fish are used for bait. According to the non-OCS assumptions produced by the University of Alaska, an excess of 2 ciliion n.t. round weight of this resource complex is available·for utilization by U.S. industry. This is not to say. however. that bottomfish are the only potential resource for future exploitation by U.S. industry. The traditional resources oay also provide some added increment of production possibilities. I base this contention on the fact that some of ~hese resources are_currently at less than historical production levels at the pr~sent time and that enlightened ca~ageoent programs which encourage ~tack rehabilitation and increased production through enhancement measures will allow production to reach historic levels over the next 20 year perfod. In terms of tonnage, the future growth potential of traditional resources is less than 10% of that available in ~be bot~oofish complex. Groundfish fisheries around the world are concucted differently than present Alaska fishing activities. This is true in North America and Canadian ports and on our own Eastern seaboard as well as in Northern Europe where similar species and in some cases similar weather and ocean conditions are present. Groundfish fishing and processing cust be carried out on a nearly year round basis. The resources are generally available during that time period with soae shifting among species groups. Also, the economic margins available to harvesters and processors are considerably less than those for the higber.~alued species which comprise most of current Alaskan production. Rising costs of energy and associated high costs of vessels and processing facilities necessitate continuous production while limiting the opportunity for distant water fisheries similar to the system employed by foreign fleets~ Trawling operations and bottomfish production in Canada including British Columbia and the Haritioe Provinces 233 ~ .. Eci · Roger Harks. Continued -3- ! J j. along the Atlantic Ocean, as well as Northern European communities in Norway, Denmark, Scotland, and so forth, are supported by communities which base themselves largely on the seafood production and related activities. It_is fairly common to find the local population either totally or substantially dependent on either fishing or processing. In many cases families will have both spouses employed in these sectors. Many of these communities outside of Alaska are also remote and have severe weather conditions. It seeos ~ost reasonable that future Alaskan fishing activities will be shaped by economic and operational concerns and take the foro of cooparable activities occurring in similar regions. In shortL it is my opinion that Alaskan fisheries, especially those of concern for these projects and including those pursued from Kodiak Island westward through the Aleutian and Pribilof ~slands will be characterized by nearly year round activity supporting both shore based and sea based processing and fishing activities with a substa~tial population that will work and live in these cocmunities. Because of these considerations I feel it most appropriate to modify some of the assumptions included in SG-3. The changes reconcended are the following: 1) The portion of the population generated by seafood production activities which live in the respective conounities should be greater than the 10-30% assumed. I recommend using 80%. 2) The above assumption should also be applied to those employed in groundfish harvesting, i.e. 80% will live in the Aleutians, etc. One other area I wish to comment on concurs the assumptions associated with the non-OCS case for these lease sales as developed in the draft repoit submitted by the University of Alaska. For the most part their assumptions are reasonably acceptable. The major exceptions I would cite are the labor estimates associated with processing activities. Both the labor estimates for shore processing and sea processing~eem quite low by comparable industrial standards. I am not certain how the figures for those assumptions were developed so it is difficult to tell where points of departure lie. Our research indicates that shore processing will require nearly 50% more people for production than their estimates show and that the labor requirement aboard catcher/processor type vessels will be more than double their estimates. 234 r1 --.··1 [ ·~· [ [ [ c L [ L [ 5 [ f L r· I L -·, • .> _;. -~ j ·" Roger Harks Co:tti.nued -4- ... Our shore base processing pl~nt estimates are built up by co=bining experie~ces of operators currently in the business and a substantial amount of input froc Canadian operators, as well as projections of needs recomoended by vendo~s of the different processing equipment and facilities. We ~a7e found that the experiences of other users of automat~d processing equipment shows that the manufacturers advertised procuction rates are generously stated. For planning purposes ve use 75% of the advertised production rate and also recog~ize that due to coffee breaks, mechanical breakdowns, and hur:.an ef'.ficiencies that production will not ge·nerally take place for the complete eight hour period in a normal operating shi~t. We plan an effective seven hours of production at the reduced. production rate. This may in part account for our average production per processing line being approximately 3,0CO ~.t. of round weight input per year versus the 4,500 n.t. of ~ound weight input per year as assuEed for the non-OCS case. In my opinion the lower fig~re is more realistic. · Regarding sea based processing based both on existing foreigc expe~ien~e with sioilar kinds of processing activities and also upon a vessel system which we conceived and had assis~ance in designing both from Nickum and Spaulding Naval ~rctitects and FIDECO, an· international fisheries consulting fir~ with considerable experience designing and operating catcher/processor vessels. It is more realistic to assume that a catcher/processor of approximately 250' OAL primarily targe~ing on Alaska pollock and producing 9,100 o.t. per year would require 80 people. These labor figures include a one-third excess over basic manning requirenents to allow crew rotat~on - a common practice in existing operations. It is my recommendation that the above assu~ptions be included for the impacts analysis associated with both St. George and Northern Aleutian lease sales. .. JJ'!as 235 Sincerely, Jeffrey J. Tobolski. President . EARL R. COMBS, INC. r-,_ r---~-----...:...CONSUlJANTS IN ECONOMICS AND PlANNING---------i 9725-S.£. 36th St. • Mercer Island. WA 98040 • (206)232-3991 ON SHORE PROCESSING 1 1 I• .Hax~mum susta~nable yield (MSY) fr6m Sea ~rant Tech. Report No. 51 ~s 2,014 1 019 m.t. A cdnsiderable portion of the resource available in the Bering Sea is likely to be harvested by the trawl fleet and future catcher/processors based in Kodiak. Ve assume that about 300,000 m.t. will be produced out of Kodiak. There is precedent for this assumption in that the Kodiak fleet currently ranges into this area yet prefers to live in Kodiak, a~d Kodiak has facilities to allow future transshipEent of fisheries products. This leaves 1,714,019 m.t. for production in the Bering Sea area. Half of the remaining harvest will be caught by catcher/processors leaving 857,009 m.t. for shore based processing. Average trawler annual catch (Sea Grant) 2,700 m.t. Tra~ler has a crew of six. 857,009 d~vided by 2,700 = 318 = vessels needed 318 vessels X 6 crew: 1,908 =primary eQployment We assume that an on shore processing p:ant will process 60,000 m.t. (132 million lbs) of fish in the round and e~ploy 606 employees. No. on shore plants=857,00~ divided by 60,000 = 14.3 plants No. primary employment=J4.3 x 606 = 8,666 employees Total primary employment for shore based harvesting and processing 8,666 + 1,908 = 10,574 AT SEA PROCESSING For planning purposes the average sea catcher/processor is assumed to be about 250' OAL and will operate tv.o processing lines on 16 hour shifts and will fish an average of 14 hours/day. This vessel would have an annual catch rate of 9,100 m.t./ year. The total resource for harvest and processing is 857,009 m.t. Consequently, 857,009 divided by 9,100 yields the need for about 94 vessels of this type. Each vessel has a crew of 60 men and a 1.33 crew rotation requirement for a total crew complement of 80 primary employees. Total primary employment for sea based process~ng is: 94 X 80 = 7,520 Total Primary Employment = 18,094 236 r-·-, ( . L [ [_' l. [~ --- [ r-· L r- ' L ECi j Background for assumptions Shore Based Processing rn The Aleutians Of the 2,014,029 c.t. of grou?dfish available in the Aleutians and Bering Sea, the following species composition was recoEmended by the Resource Availability Task Team for the Svstecs Strategy to Suooort Fisheries Development in Alaska study prepared for Economic Development Administration and National Marine Fisheries Service. 1980. The Resourc~ Task Teao_~as made up of: Jim Branson Bert Larkins Phil Rigby Rick Dutton Jeff' Tobolski Leo Guluka NPFMC, Anchorage NMFS, Northwest & AK Center ADF&:G Icicle Seafoods, Inc. Earl R. Combs, Inc. (ECI) Earl R. Combs, Inc. (ECI) The Bering Sea and Aleutian Resource Availability Species Pollock Cod POP F·latfish Other Total % of Catch 68.9 2.5 4 .. 6 22.2 1 • 8 100 % The above resource composition was used to design a 60,000 n.t~ groundfish processing unit. The plant would occupy 210,000 sq ft of space. The plant would be comprised of 32 separate processing lines operating for 210 days a year with 8 hour shifts per day at 90% capacity. The lines consist of: 25 cod/pollock lines 1 POP line 3 Flatfish lines 3 Rand filieting lines for over size and under size fish A typical automated cod/pollock line employs 20 people and is rated at 3,000 m.t. output per year. This line operates at 75% efficiency due to_ downtime, maintenance, and delays for 7 of the 8 hours in a shift (due to employee downtime) which results in a 2,000 m.t. annual outputw The perch/rockfish and flatfish lines are 4,500 m.t. lines with an annual output of 3,000 m.t. per year at 75% line efficiency a~d 87.3~ labor efficiency. The hand filleting line is a 2,250 m.t. line with an annual output of 1,500 m.t. per year. 237 Ec1· A typical perch line employs 28 people while the flatfish and hand rilleting lines employ 5 and 32 employees, respectively. The plant also uses three deboning units for better waste recovery employing three p~ople. 52 supervisory and other operational employees are also used. Th~y include dock workers, scale and inspection personnel, warehousemen, freezer packers, mechanics and plant and floor managers. The indirect labor includes 17 other employees which include plant managers, marketing and clerical ana bookkeeping personnel. Total plant employment is 606 employees receiving $9,127,000 annually in wages; $12,321,000 with benefits. Enployment 60.000 rn.t. Unit U employees Indirect.Personnel 17 Supervisory/General 52 Cod/Poll~ck lines 429 Perch/Rockfish lines 28 Flatfish line 14 Hand Fillet line 63 Deboning --1 Total 6 06 Cod/Pollock Line (single line*) :{E 1 i nes 25 1 3 . 3 32 f eijlolovees Washer Header & Gutter Filleting Machine Operator Skinner Trimmer/Butcher Packer .. Equipment Used Roundfish washer Infeed table Baader 16i H&G machine Fish el.evator 238 1 1 1 1 8 _a 20 Nunb.er 1 1 1 1 [ l. [ I L u [ [_j [ [ f' L r· I . L ECI" _] _) Baader 189 cod/pollock ~illeting machine Arenco CUS 80 skinning machine Candl.i..og and trimming table .. Fillet washer/phosphate applicator Pack:in; table 1 1 1 1 1 * ~hen ocltiple lines in use the number of personnel required cay decrease as soce personnel could operate·more than one wachine o~ similar design Perch/Rockfish Line (single line~) Eo;>per tender Eeader and Gutter Filleting machine operator Skinner ~ricmer/3utcher Packer Eo:1irinent Used 3100 1::> Hopper riasher/D escaler Infeed table Baader 417 head cutter Baader 195 ~illeting machine Are.oco CUS 80 skinning machine Candling/Trioming table F:illet washer/phosphate applicator Packi..ng table * See foot~ote for cod/pollock line 'Washer Eeader/Filleter Packer Flatfish Line 239 t eaoloyees 1 1 1 1 12 1.2. 28 Number 1 1 .1 2 2 2 1 1 1 f Employee 1 2 _a 5 ECf· I Eauioment Used Pneu~atic tipper Arenco CUS head cutter Dressing area Wash tank Hand Fillet Line Hopper operator Incentive filleter Weighing Skinner Butcher/Trimmer Packers Eou-ipment Used Hopper 2300 lb capacity Flohr washer/descaler Weighing scales -filleting table ABCO Incentive filleting table Roller table TRIO skinning machine Washer/phosphate applicator Packing table Sea Based Processing In The Aleutians NuT"Iber 1 2 2 1 ~ Enolovee 1 16 2 1 6 ~ 32. Nunber 1 1 2 1 1 1 1· 1 Sea based processing will perhaps be carried out by vessels of-various configurations. Our own investigations and discussions with knowledgeable people in the industry;-~ however, lead us to believe that most vessels for this purpose will be in the ~00' plus CAL. More specifically we believe that a vessel of 250' CAL would be required to harvest and process pollock and other groundfish species in the Bering Sea. and Aleutian areas. Eadh one of these vessels would conduct about nine trips a year, each trip lasting four weeks or 30 days. Esti~ated catch for this vessel is about 9,100 o.t./year. It would have enough crew to fish and process the catch and man the vessels. The crew on any trip would number at least 60 men. Therefore, the vessel must have enough staterooms each accoooodating four people at the most. Because there must be 240 f~ \!__ -· r~ \'_- J~ 1' f c - L; [ t f' L [ [ r [ b r "-" r~• L r . L r , I L, ' . ECI some rotation in the crew, any vessel must have one-third more crew over and above the trip crew waiting in port to substitute for the next trip. This ~eans that a total of 80 people have to be attached to a single vessel. A design for this kind of vessel was prepared for Earl · R. Combs, Inc. (ECI) by Nickum & Spaulding. It was reviewed by FIDECO and found to be ·a good representativ~ of the practical realities of sea based operations. This design compares very well with these of some vessel used i~ foreign sea based operations in the Bering Sea. A copy of this design is attached and shows various profiles including: inboard, boat ~eck, upper deck~ main deck and double bottom plans. It gives a detailed configuration of the var~ous spaces and their purposes. 241 · ECJ· Position Ship's Mas~er !st ~a~e 2nd ~a~e C:hief !::lgi::ee:::- ~nd nsst. ~g~neer ?r<>~>.lc'tion Cr e.,.· * Fis~ing S~~ri~tencer.t rishing;-weck ere~ C.'"lief Cook. Ass~. Cook * The production crew ~arks t~o shifts [ r, [ Fur~r 1 [ l [ 1 l [ 1 l .. "[ .. 2 . ~5 ~~, L_ 1 -!0 [ 1 2 [ 2 ·L__, 60 [ en t~o production lines [ _j Proiected Resource Growth Rate ·It is of our opinion that th~ U.S. fishing industry growth during the next 20 year can be approximated by a bell shaped type curve. The early stage will be typically a period of slow cautious growth as the industry establishes itself. This will be followed by a period of rapid growth as other firms begin to take advantage of the opportunities. the last stage will be a period of deceleration as MSY's are reached. The problem facing the industry in the early stages will be many. The personnel lack the technical knowledge and skills necessary to exploit the resources. This will require an extensive period of training,_experimenting, and trial and error. In addition, the 1979 average composite wholesale groundfish price to processors was approximately $.98 and industry sources feel that it will requi~e around-$1.05 for the industry to break even without having to target on the higher valued species. Therefore, the early growth of the industr~ will be slow. As skill levels increase and prices rise, more and more opportunities will present themselves to the industry. This industry ca~ be expected to grow quite rapidly for a period of time. Then as the more productive fishing grOunds are utilized harvesters will look to less productive areas for growth. In addition, the higher valued groundfish species will then approach their MSY's and a period of deceleration should occur. Therefore, we feel that a typical industry growth curve is approximated by a normal distribution and our projected resource growth for .the Aleutians reflects this assumption. ·' 243 . 1 ... ~\ ., r, __ c:--~r ___________________ l[ 1,800 1 '500 1, 200 1,000 M.T. 900 600 300 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 PROJECTED FISHERIES RESOURCE UTILIZATION IN THE BERING SEA AND ALEUTIAN ISLANDS 244 100% 80% 60% [ r L: ,, L f ·[ L Percent 40% 20% [ [j t [ f' L ,~ I . L N +::> tn i.J ' '~ l' L." ,, J U,, l. L. , J ' J Residency Employment for Ground.Ush Productio·n Aleutian Islands Resi- Ground fish Onshore Number Harvest Number o£ Process Percent dcncy of Empl?.y-On::horS/ Emplgy-Employ llcsi-9 Employ-Vessels~/ ~-. Plan':_!!.. ~-!!!£!!L dcnEJ__I !!!£!!L Year Harvest 11 l'roc:ss 21 {1 1 000 m.t.}-Portlon- 1980 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1981 0 0 0 0 0 o· 0 0 0 1982 50 25 9 54 1 606 660 10 66 1983 100 50 19 114 1 606 720 10 72 1984 150 75 28 168 1 606 77'• 10 77 1985 200 100 37 222 2 1,212 1,43'• 10 143 1986 250 125 46 276 2 1,212 1,'•88 10 149 1987 350 175 65 390 3 1,818 2,208 15 331 1988 450 225 ' 83 498 '· 2 .'•2'· 2,922 20 584 1989 600 300 111 666 5 3,030 3,6% 25 924 1990 750 375 139 834 6 3,636 4 ,lt70 30 1,341 1991 900 450 167 1,002 8 '•,848 5,850 35 2,0lo8 1992 1,000 500 IllS 1' 110 8 4,848 5,958 '•0 2,383 1993 1,150 575 213 1,278 10 6,060 7,338 '·5 3,302 1994 1,300 650 241 1,446 11 6,666 8,112 50 4,056 1995 1,350 675 250 1,500 11 6,666 8,166 55 4,491 1996 1 ,t,oo 700 2.59 1,554 12 7,272 8,826 60 5,296 1997 1,500 750 278 1,668 13 7,878 9,546 65 6,205 1998 1,600 800 296 1,776 13 7,1178 9 ,65'• 70 6,758 1999 1,650 825 306 1,836 14 8,464 10,320 75 .. 7, 7ltO 2000 1,700 850 315. 1,890 }1, 8 ,t,at, 10,374 80 8,299 Y Year 2000 total from Sea Grant (Bering-Norton Petroleum Development Scenarios Commercial Fish Industry Impact Analysis). Shape of growth from Earl R. Combs, Inc. memo (July 18, 1980). ?:1 Assumes half of processing onshore, half offshore (Sea 'Grant). ~/Assumes 2,700 m.t./vesscl (Combs). ~/Assumes 6/crcw (Combs). 5/ . . -Assumes 60,000 m.t./plant (Combs), £1 Assumes 606/plsnt (Combs). 2/ Assumes 80 percent long-run residency (Combs) for onshore processing with the rate halved for catcher/ processors. This is graduated from the current 10 percent rote assuming an initial 5-ycar lag. .J ~ Total Resi-Resi- Catcher/ Number Percent dency dency Process 21 of 71 Emplgy-Hcsi-Employ-Employ-UCE5_Y..~/ Portion-Vessels-mcnl:.-mcnt ment 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 o. 0 0 25 3 2ltO 10 21. 90 50 5 ltOO 10 40 112 75 8 6ltO 10 6l. 1111 100 11 BBO 10 88 231 125 14 1,120 10 112 261 175 19 1,520 10 152 483 225 25 2,000 10 200 78'• 300 33 2,640 10 264 1,188 375 41 3,280 15 492 1,833 450 '•9 3,920 15 588 2,636 N 500 55 4,400 20 880 3t263 -+:> 575 63 5,040 20 1,008 4,310 (j) 650 71 5,680 25 1,420 5,476 675 74 5,920 25 1,480 .5,971 700 77 6,160 30 1; 8ft8 7,144 750 82 6,560 30 1,968 8,173 800 88 7,040 35 2,464 9,222 . ,. 825 91 7,280 35 2,548 10,288 850 93 7,440 40 2,976 11,275 '!:.I Assumes half of processing onshore, half offshore (Sea Grant.) II Assumes 9 1 100 m.t./vessel (Combs). ~I Assumes SO/crew (Combs). 2/ Assumes 80 percent long-run residency (Combs) for onshore processing with the rate halved for catcher/processors. This is grriduated from the current 10 percent rate assuming an initial 5-ycar lag. -r-J en en Cl ~ r-J. rr. rJ r--j ~i ,...__..., .:-l ·r---1 .~ i:---l -, j _j Memorandum l!nited States Department of the Interior BUREAU OF LAND MANAGEMENT AlASKA OOTER CONI'INENTIU. SHEI.F OFFICE Post Office Box 1159 Anchorage, Alaska 99510 September 12, 1980 To: Acting Coordinator, Socioeconomic Studies Program From: Socioeconomic Specialist Subject: Assumptions Regarding Bottomfishery Development The potential for bottomfishery industry development in the Aleutian Islands by the end of this century to cause social and economic structural change is considerable. Thus accurate estimate of the degree of industry development is important for building a base against which to measure OCS impacts. The two major considerations to estimate are total domestic production and local residency of the production employment. For the St. George studies to proceed, assumptions were made regarding these (see attached July 23 memo) • Those assumptions were optimistic towards the possibility of bottomfishery development. Due to the significant structural changes such development will cause, these assumptions were met by resistance from some contractors. This forced us to reassess these assumptions one final time before requiring the contractors to go ahead based .on them. In the last several weeks we have done some thinking on the matter, some reading, and had some in-and out-house discussion with knowledgeable persons. We have decided to uphold our assumptions based on the follmving: The pivotal factor necessary for development of the resource is a federal/state policy tmvards commitment to such. The policy is currently developed, and is energetic. Studies and planning programs have been implemented. It is expected that subsidy funds will be available. Extended domestic jurisdiction has been established. Two of our fisheries contractors, Sea Grant and Earl Combs, have independently projected this optimistic development. Save Energy and You Serve America! 247 JN REPLY REl'Ell. TO 3331.5 Richard Careaga, planner for Dutch Harbor, is planning for 20,000 people by the year 2000. 2 Per capita consumption of fish is increasing. Aggregate supply is essentially fixed. This, coupled with the fact that over the past 10 years the real wholesale price of bottomfish has been growing at a rate of 7% above the food processors' cost index and is expected to continue doing such, indicates prices should accelerate. The capital requirements for such development are relatively modest (approx. $3 billion). Many of the vessels that have been built for the Alaska shellfish fleets in the past few years have been designed to allow them to enter the groundfish fishery as it becomes more profitable and as the shellfish seasons become shorter. The increasing number of joint ventures indicate the increasing number of bottomfishing vessels. They are also a logical inter- mediate step toward full development. Large processors are currently buying smaller existing plants to operate and develop during down time. 248 [ [ [ I I L __ , [ [1 _, [ [ I- l r~ I L APPENDIX C ~ OCS TOTAL DIRCT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN 249 N U1 0 Year 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986. 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 APPENDIX C TABLE C-1. OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT: Mining Total 0 0 0 131 198 232 198 97 0 0 EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN SEAR 0 0 0 50 64 72 65 44 0 0 Exploration Only Construction Total 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 SEAR 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Transportation Total 0 0 0 57 . 93 110 93 20 0 0 SEAR 0 0 0 23 37 46 39 8 0 0 *No SEAR adjustment performed on headquarters employment. 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total 0 0 0 188 292 342 292 177 0 0 Total SEAR 0 0 0 73 101 119 105 53 0 0 SOURCE: Total direct OCS employment from Alaska OCS Office. SEAR adjustments performed by ISER. ...-. ~. J r--. l . _..,_ ,j i.u • l ' I j V .~.,_] 1_' ·~) J . J APPENDIX C TABLE C-2. OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN Mean Only Mining Construction Trans~ortation HQTS* Total Year Total SEAR Total SEAR Total SEAR Total SEAR 1980 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1981 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1982 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1983 299 84 37 18 143 57 0 480 160 N 1984 468 118 111 55 227 91 0 805 264 (.TI 1985 535 136 753 172 320 162 0 1608 470 _, 1986 468 122 1806 190 407 254 0 2681 565 1987 733 244 4721 1165 470 363 0 5924 1771 1988 769 247 3871 1075 670 616 16 5310 1954 1989 1148 795 2427 873 940 880 31 4515 2574 1990 1064 738 1241 619 720. 711 101 3026 2189 1991 951 710 0 0 720 711 133 1671 1554 1992 1096 758 1816 1602 1993 1280 819 2000 1663 1994 1157 778 1877 1622 1995 1035 738 1755 1582 1996 920 700 1640 1544 1997 1096 758 1816 1602 1998 1280 819 2000 1663 1999 1157 778 1877 1622 2000 1035 738 0 0 720 711 133 1755 1582 *No SEAR adjustment performed on headquarters employment. SOURCE: · Total direct OCS employment from Alaska OCS Office. SEAR adjustments per·formed by ISER. APPENDIX D OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT BY PLACE OF WORK AND BY PLACE OF RESIDENCE: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN 253 N U1 +:> Year 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 APPENDIX D TABLE D-1. OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT BY PLACE OF WORK AND BY PLACE OF RESIDENCE: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN Exploration Only By Region Statewide Region 2 Region 4 Region 5 EMP1 RES 0 0 0 0 58 Not in AK Total Total Dir. EMP RES 0 0 0 188 292 342 292 177 0 0 0 0 EMP RES 0 0 0 0 15 21 24 22 12 0 0 0 81 95 83 42 0 0 0 1There is no headquarters employment in this case. EMP RES 0 0 0 0 115 190 223 187 123 0 0 0 SEAR EMP OCS EMP 0 0 0 73 101 119 105 53 0 0 0 0 188 292 342 292 177 0 0 .~ --! LiJ \.., I ,u L.L, ,lJ \..;. "' j \J .. I , i . J L. , J . J APPENDIX D TABLE D-2. OCS TOTAL DIRECT AND SEAR ADJUSTED EMPLOYMENT BY PLACE OF WORK AND BY PLACE OF RESIDENCE: EXPLORATION ONLY AND MEAN CASES, ST. GEORGE BASIN Mean Only B,t Region Statewide Region 2 Region 4 Region 5 Not in AK Total Total Dir. Year EMP RES EMP RES EMP RES EMP RES SEAR EMP OCS EMP ~t 1980 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1981 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 N 1982 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 U1 U1 1983 480 1 0 32 0 127 0 320 160 480 1984 805 2 52 0 209 542 264 805 1985 1608 19 87 0 364 1138 470 1608 1986 2681 45 106 0 415 2125 565 2681 1987 5924 149 333 0 1288 4154 1771 5924 1988 5294 391 314 16 1248 3357 1954 5310 1989 4484 624 395 31 1559 1937 2579 4515 1990 2925 561 320 101 1309 836 2189 3026 \ 1991 1538 540 186 133 828 117 1554 1671 1992 1683 195 867 214 1602 1816 1993 1867 206 917 337 1663 2000 1994 1744· 194 888 255 1662 1877 1995 1622 184 858 173 1582 1755 1996 1507 175 829 96 1544 1640 199:7 1683 186 876 214 1602 1816 1998 1867 197 925 338 1663 2000 1999 1744 187 895 255 1622 1877 2000 1622 5 0 0 182 133 860 0 173 1582 1755 TABLE NOTES Note: 11 EMP 11 is tota 1 direct OCS employment in the indicated region and includes both resident and nonresident em-_ ployment. 11 RES 11 is direct OCS employment of residents of the indicated region. Hence, the sum of the 11 RES 11 columns for Alaska is equal to SEAR adjusted total direct OCS employment, while the sum of 11 EMP 11 columns equals total direct OCS employment. SOURCE: Total direct OCS employment from Alaska OCS Office. Allocation of t~esidents to regions and SEAR adjustment by ISER. 256 [ n [ [: [ [ [ [ I' L [ l [ c 6 [ [ r: L r~ I . L ...,. :::l -REFERENCES Alaska Consultants, Inc. 11 City of Sand Point Comprehensive Plan 11 (Alaska State Housing Authority, Anchorage) 1970. Alaska Department of Fish and Game. Alaska Catch and Production: Commercial Fisheries Statistics. Various years. Alaska Department of Labor. Statistical Quarterly. Various quarters, 1964-1978. Alaska Department of Labor. Population Estimates by Census Division. Various years. Alaska Department of Labor. Alaska Labor Force Estimates. Various years. Alaska Department of Labor. Alaska Economic Trends. Various years . Alaska Sea Grant Program. Draft Final Western Alaska and Bering-Norton Petroleum Deve1o ment Scenarios: Commercial Fishing Industry Analysis BLM/Alaska OCS Office; Anchorage) April 25, 1980. Arthur D. Little, Inc. The Development of a Bottomfish Industry: Strategies for the State of Alaska. (Technical Appendix, Vol. II). A Report to the Office of the Governor. Arctic Environmental Information and Data Center. Village Profiles for False Pass, St. Paul, St. George, Belkofski, Nelson Lagoon, Nikolski, Atka, Akutan, and King Cove. (Prepared for the Alaska Department of Community and Regional Affairs) May 1978. Bomhoff and Associates, Inc. City of Sand Point Comprehensive Plan (June 1977). Huskey, Lee and Jim Kerr. Small Community Population Impact t~odel and A lication to the Berin -Norton OCS Lease Sale Area. Institute of Social and Economic Research; Anchorage March 1980. Jones, Dorothy M. Pattern? of Village Growth and Decline in the Aleutians. (Institut~ of Social, Economic, and Government Research; Fairbanks) October 1973. 257 ---·~ --....... ·-·· . Mathematical Sciences Northwest, Inc., and Human Resources Planning Institute~ Inc.· A Social and Economic Impact Study of.Offshore Petroleum and Natural Gas Development in Alaska: Phase I Final Report. (Department of the Interior, Bureau of Land Management; Anchorage) October 15, 1976. North Pacific Fishery Management Council. \~estern Alaska. King Crab Draft Fishery Management Plan (Anchorage) May 20, 1980. Rogers, George W. 11 Critique of the Arthur D. Little, Inc., Analysis and Recommendations for State Policy and Directions for Developing a Bottomfish Industry for Alaska ... (Alaska Legislative Affairs Agency; Juneau) April 24, 1979. Rogers, George W., et al. Measuring the Socioeconomic Impacts of Alaska's Fisheries. (Institute of Social and Economic Research; Anchorage) April 1980. Scott, Michael J. 11 Prospects for a Bottomfish Industry in Alaskan in Alaska Review of Social and Economic Conditions (Vol. XVII, No. 1, April 1980) pp. 2-31. Tryck, Nyman and Hayes. Recommended Community Deve l opmen·l. Plan: City of Unalaska, Alaska. Prepared for the city of Unalaska. November 1977. \ 258 [ n L [ [ c IL [ [ [ . ' p L r: L [