HomeMy WebLinkAboutAPA1589-~
I , '· u
: Ji
I
I
i I!
TO
794.5
.N43
1980
PJ\ ECONOl'HC EVALUATim~ OF THE POTENTIAL FOR
RECYCLING wASTE Kt:..TERIALS II\ A:.l'i!CHORAGE, ALASKA
NSTITUTE OF SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC RESEARCH
UNIVERSITY OF ALASKA
Fairbanks • Anchorage • Juneau
c
[
b
c
G
E
c
n u
[
c
b
LO
0
CD
C\1
C\1 ,-
,-
0
0
LO
LO
"" C")
C")
Al'J. ECONOHIC EVALUATION OF THE POTENTIAL FOR
RECYCLING WASTE l1ATERIALS IN LNCHORP.GE, ALASKA
By
\.Jilliam E. Nebesky
Institute of Social and Economic Research
University of Alaska
Final Report to the
House Finance Committee
of
The Alaska State Legislature
Hay 1, 1980
ARLIS
Alaska Resources Library & lnformationSem"oes
Library Building, Suite 111
32J 1 Providence Drive
Anchorage, AK 99508-4614
TABLE OF CONTENTS
LIST OF TABLES
LIST OF FIGURES
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
INTRODUCTION.
Part
I. RECYCLING: CONCEPTS AND ISSUES
~~at is Recycling?
The Benefits of Recycling
Institutional Constraints
II. :H...\TERIAL THROUGHPUT
CoiiL.'1lodity Hovement
Paper .
Newsprint .
Corrugated Containers
High-grade Paper Stock
Glass· .
Aluminum Cans
Tin Cans .
The Structure of Transportation
Solid Waste Management .
Collection
Processing and Disposal
Summary .
III. CURRENT RECYCLING STATUS .
IV.
Scrap Metal Collection
Waste Oil and Waste Paper Recovery
Full-line R~cycling: The Alaska Center for
the Environment Recycle Center
Summary •
RECYCLING SECNARIOS
Basic Scenario
Recovery and Revenue
Recovery Technology
Collection
Processing
Freight
n
c
i 0
iv
v c
1 B
5 c
5
7 c 10
15 ~
16 n 17
18 LJ
19
20 C 22
27
28 c 33 B 37
38 B 42
51
-. 53 6
54 ~ 58
60 Q 70
. . 73 ~ .
75
76 p,
79 L
80
81 R 84
L.-.....l
-t
[
[
c
E
[
n u
[
D
IV.
v.
RECYCLING SCENARIOS (cont.)
Commercial Feasibility
Social Feasibility .
Buy-back Scenario .
Comi11ercial Feasibility
Social Feasibility .
Office Paper Collection Scenario
Commercial Feasibili~y
Social Feasibility
Summary
PUBLIC POLICY .
Policy Proposals
Recycling Recovery Sector
Subsidy •
Central Recovery Wholesaler
Depletion Deduction .
Tax Credit •
Com.r,mni ty Participation
Compulsory Office Paper Separation
Returnable Beverage Container Legislation
S um.'Ua ry
BIBLIOGRAPHY
87
94
101
102
104
104
107
110
112
121
127
128
128
133
139
140
142
142
143
150
155
Number
1-1
1-2
2-1
2-2
2-3
2-4
2-5
2-6
2-7
2-8
2-9
2-10
2-11
2-12
3-.1
3-2
LIST OF TABLES
Title
Energy Used in Processing Virgin and
Recycled Materials .
Recycling Rates for Selected Commodities
Commodity Imports to Anchorage
(1978 and 1992)
Railbelt Paper and Newsprint Imports
West Coast Paper Prices .
Inbound Computer Print Out and IBH
TP~ Cards for 1979 .
Glass Containers by End-Use in Anchorage
Recovery Potential, Harket Price and Freight
·Factor for Several Secondary Materials
Breakdmm of Backhaul Materials and Revenue
Potential .
Southbound Shipping Specifications for
Waste Paper
Anchorage Bowl Waste Disposal .
Residential and Commercial Composition of
1979 Mixed Solid Waste
Annual Total Coot of Refuse Collection .
Annual Total Operating and Capital Costs
for Processing and Disposal .
Waste and Scrap Haterials Outbound from Anchorage,
Whittier and Seward Ports in 1973, 1977 and 1978
Metal Salvage by Commodity in 1979
i
8
9
16
17
21
23
25
31
33
36
37
39
41
50
54
56
[
c
[
[
r L
[
D
lJ
~-·~ L
[
[
D
[
[
n u
[
List of Tables (Cont.)
Number
3-3
3-4
3-5
3-6
4-1
4-2
4-3
4-4
4-5
4-6
4-7
4-8
4-9
4-10
4-11
Title
Recycling Participation at the Alaska Center
for the Environment Recycle Center .
Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle
Center Computer Paper Pick-Up Frequency
Quarterly Report, Alaska Center for the
Environment Recycle Center (November and
December, 1979; January, 1980)
External Benefits and Costs Estimates for
54 Tons of Paper Recovery .
The Quantity and Composition of Residential
Haste Per Household (HH) for Selected Materials.
Total Residential and Commercial Quantity and
Composition of Recyclable Materials
Basic Scenario Revenue Potential
Basic Scenario Processing Requirements
Basic Recycling Scenario -Equipment Costs
for Collection, Processing, and General
Operation
Basic Recycling Scenario -Personnel and
Payroll .
Basic Scenario Freight Specifications and
Costs
Basic Scenario Distribution of Revenues and
Costs by Material
Summary Statement of Revenues and Expenses
for Basic Scenario and Basic Scenario with
Modified Product Mix
Home Separation Requirements
Social Feasibility of Basic Scenario and
Basic with Modified Product Mix .
ii
61
62
65
69
76
78
79
83
85
86
88
89
93
95
96
List of Tables (Cont.)
Number
4-12
4-13
4-14
4-15
4-16
4-17
4-18
5-1
5-2
5-,3
Title
Social Feasibility Under Assumptions More
Favorable to Recycling
Buy-Back Policy .
Net Social Benefits and Costs in the Buy-Back
Scenario Under Alternate Assumptions on
Participation and on Interpretation of
Non-Market Benefits and Costs
Operation and Equipment Requirements for
500 Tons of Annual Office Paper Recovery
Summary Statement of Revenues and Expenses
for Buy-Back and Buy-Back Plus Office
Paper Scenarios
Comparison of Net Social Benefits and Costs
in the Buy-Back and Office Source Separation
Scenarios
Comparative Benefit/Cost Summary of Recycling
Scenarios Under Alternate Interpretations
of External Benefits and Costs
Subsidy Guidelines .
Comparative Statement of Annual Revenues
and Expenses for the Recovery Wholesaler
and Independent Collectors
Economic Gains to Various Groups as a Result
of Recovery Wholesale Services
iii
99
102
105
108
109
111
117
132
136
138
[
[
c
r
LJ
['
I ;
l_j
F D
.I=!
L
[
[
c
c
[
[
n
L
[
~·
Q
~
8
Number
2-1
2-2
4-1
5-1
LIST OF FIGURES
Title
Comparison of Anchorage Bowl Annual Inbound
and Recoverabl~ Quantities for Selected
Commodities
1980 Assessed Value for Select Land Parcels
In or Near the Municipal Landfill Site .
A Comparison of the Range of Net Social Benefits
Between the Basic Scenario and the Basic Scenario
with Modified Product Mix
Product Mix Matrix
iv
32
46
101
125
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This study reports on an economic analysis of the potential for
recycling waste material in Anchorage, Alaska. The purpose of the study
is to assist the House Finance Committee of the Alaska State Legislature
and other interested parties in the development of public policy to
strengthen private and public sector involvement in material recovery
for recycling. Funding for this research was made available by the House
Finance Committee.
The analysis of recycling potential encompasses three broad questions:
1.
2.
3.
Hm.;r much Haste material is available for recycling in
Anchorage?
Hhat is the current extent of Anchorage-based recycling?
Hhat are the economic effects of expanding current levels
of recycling?
The results of the analysis are then used to highlight the potential
effects of several public policy proposals to increase recycling.
The scope of the analysis is limited to Anchorage for two reasons.
First, the nature of the study requires considerable detail regarding
the source, quality, composition, and market for specific materials cDn-
sumed in a community or local economy. In many instances, data was
missing or inaccurate and had to be estimated. Thus, in order to retain
a manageable level ,of detail, the analysis is confined to a single loca-
tion and to a specific set of materials, including: tin and aluminum cans,
glass, and several grades of waste paper. Second, Anchorage comprises a
substantial portion of statewide economic activity and compared with most
Alaska cities is located nearest to "stateside" secondary materials mar-
kets. Thus, if recycling potential is marginal in Anchorage, it would
be unlikely elsewhere in Alaska.
v
[
[
[
c
E
L
[
c
b
H L
[
[
[
c
E
[
f' u
[
r
lj
B
D
I conservatively estimate the annual quantity of secondary tin,
aluminum, glass, and paper available for recovery and recycling in
Anchorage to be 30 thousand tons. This compares by vJeight to about
one-fifth of total mixed solid waste generated and throvm. avJay from
residential and commercial sources. The determination of the quantity
of recoverable secondary materials takes into account factors such as
contamination and limited accessibility.
Each ton recycled reduces by an equivalent amount the quantity of
waste that must be collected, processed, and disposed in the municipal
landfill. In 1979, total waste management costs for 160 thousand tons
of municipal refuse was $9.8 million, or $61 per ton. For the purpose
of calculating the impact of recycling on the cost of waste management,
I estimate that 20 percent of total ~:vaste management cost is variable
and therefore affected by quantity reductions. This amounts to less
than 12 dollars per ton and assumes that the frequency and, therefore,
cost of collection is unchanged.
Backhaul rates for southbound com.-rnunity movement from Anchorage to
S~attle are not likely to be reduced by carriers. Southbound container
movement is 90 percent unused. Thus, ·revenues from forward commodity
movement cover 80 percent of backhaul shipping expenses. Lower south-
bound rates would ±urther shift the backhaul deficit on forwa:ul c.:uumtodity
movement unless southbound commodity movement increased somewhat dramati-
cally in response to southbound tariff reductions.
On average, only 2 percent of the annual quantity of available
secondary materials is actually recovered and shipped to stateside
secondary materials markets. Private sector involvement in Anchorage-
based collection for recycling is composed cf small-scale operations
that specialize in a narrow range of commercially desirable secondary
materials. The Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center (ACERC)
represents an exception to the above structure in that it recovers a
"full line" of secondary materials including newsprint, computer print
out (CPO), IBM tabulating cards (tab cards), tin and aluminum cans, used
vi
motor oil, and worn-out car batteries. Also, ACERC is nonprofit and
depends partly on public funds to cover expenses. Data from the first
three months of operations suggest that, in order to break even, ACERC's
recovery would have to increase five-fold from 18-to-90 tons of newsprint,
CPO, and tab cards per month. However, this required break-even quantity
represents only 3 percent participation in waste separation and recovery
by Anchorage residents and commercial institutions.
Several factors limit recycling potential in Anchorage:
Instate recycling potential. Prospects for instate production of
recycled commodities are limited by factors identical to those that
limit the potential for the development of a broader-based manufacturing
sector in Anchorage. In general, these include relatively high labor
and capital costs, confined local market demand, and high freight costs
for in-and outbound commodity movement.
Just as the extra cost of shipping commodities into Alaska creates
an incentive for local commodity production, the cost of shipping second-
ary materials to external markets for recycling represents an economic
stimulant for instate production of recycled commodities from locally
generated secondary materials. The freight factor from Anchorage to
Seattle typically absorbs 25 percent of revenue potential and places
Alaska recyclers at a substantial competitive disadvantage in relation
to recyclers located in closer proximity to end-use markets.
Nevertheless, the high inc.iJeu~.:e uf ~o:uWlllut.llLy lmports into Alaska
suggests that the hoigher costs of local commodity production generally
outweigh the transportation disadvantage felt by outside producers. The
same conditions apply to local production of recycled commodities; that
is, the high cost of local recycled commodity production from secondary
materials outweighs the cost disadvantage of transporting materials to
"stateside" markets.
vii
[
c
[
[
c
LJ
c
D
h
L
[~ ... L-
__ j
-~
D
Although the potential for local recycling ~s important from the
standpoint both of energy and resource conservation and of development
of local industrial capacity, this report focuses on the economic feasi-
bility of Anchorage-based recycling recovery systems that collect, sort,
compact, and market secondary materials to existing end-use markets in
Seattle.
Externalities. Steady patterns of rising secondary materials prices
suggest that recognition of energy savings from recycling is becoming
more widespread and, as a result, demand for secondary materials is on
the increase.
Despite the effect of rising demand, secondary materials continue
to be undervalued as a consequence of the narrow interpretation of costs
and benefits in private sector markets.
If we broaden the definition of costs and benefits to include non-
market factors. such as savings from landfill diversion, then additional
"external" benefits arise outside the private sector that have the poten-
tial to compensate for private sector losses.
Until these external benefits are reflected in prices explicitly,
secondary materials will continue to be underutilized. Equivalently, by
passing up the opportunity to recycle, extra unnecessary waste management
costs (equal to foregone benefits) are imposed on both resident and com-
mercial sectors of the Anchorage economy.
Economies of $cale and citizen participation. The scale of material
recovery is largely a function of residential and commercial participation
in waste separation. Thus, the degree of citizen participation is a prin-
cipal determinant of economies of scale to the recycler.
Although the recycler is able to influence participation through
buy-back programs, advertising, and educational campaigns, the level of
viii
material recovery and, therefore, the quantity of marketable supply is
not under the recyclers' direct control.
I apply ~ro~~riteria to evaluate the economic feasibility of ex-
panding material recovery beyond current levels. The first criterion,
. .
designated "commercial feasibility," employs market prices and assumes
customary commercial financing for all plant and equipment without ·
government intervention or assistance. In the second criterion, desig-
nated "social feasibility," I quantify several "external" benefits and
costs and use them to adjust private benefits and costs subsumed under
commercial feasibility. Social feasibility reflects the combined effect
of benefits and costs in both private and public sectors of the economy.
To illustrate the economic significance of factors not reflected in
market prices, we construct two competing definitions of social feasibility.
In the pessimistic definition, I interpret time and effort in household
waste separation as an "opportunity" cost that is equal to the value of
foregone leisure or employment. Household waste separation of newsprint,
glass, and tin and aluminum cans requires about one hour per month, or
about $100 annually for participating households.
The optimistic definition ignores this effect under the assumption
that waste separation may be easily integrated into routine household
functions and, in fact, creates compensating benefits from reduced
household garbage disposal.
Both interpretations of social feasibility recognize reduced waste
management costs from processing and disposing less refuse and extra
savings from delayed expenditures on new landfill site development. In
the optimistic interpretation of social feasibility, I assume further
that recycling would reduce the frequency of municipal refuse collection
and therefore create additional (though modest) savings in the overall
waste management system.
ix
[
[
[
[
[
[
I~
L
[
r
b
h
L
P. L.
i
L.
r
r
6
fJ
L
I ignore the effect of environmental amenities from litter and pol-
lution reduction in both interpretations of social feasibility and there-
fore understate the level of external benefits from recycling.
I apply the feasibility criteria to three expanded recycling scenarios
constructed from specific assumptions or product mix and profit orientation.
All scenarios assume that 25 percent of Anchorage households and commercial
institutions regularly engage in waste separation of specific materials
for delivery to or collection by the recycle center.
The basic recycling scenario depicts a nonprofit, full-line recycle
center that depends on secondary material donations by household residents
and commercial institutions. In the buy-back scenario, the recycle center
is profit-oriented and offers to pay consumers for specific secondary
materials. The basic and buy-back scenarios are distinguished mainly by
the profile of materials they recover. Commercially unprofitable mater-
ials are omitted from the buy-back scenario. The office-collection
scenario modifies conditions in the buy-back scenario by introducing a
comprehensive program in high-grade ledger paper separation and collec-
tion from state office buildings.
Several important observations emerge from the feasibility analysis
of alternate, expanded recycling scenarios. They are:
1.
2.
3.
None of the recycling scenarios were able to satisfy
the criteria for commercial feasibility. Recycling
under the modified-product mix in the buy-back scenario
would be profitable only under conditions in which re-
cyclable~ are donated by residents and commercial groups.
None of the recycling scenarios were able to satisfy the
criteria for social feasibility under the pessimistic
interpretation of external costs and benefits. The public
cost of household separation, evaluated at the average
wage rate in Anchorage, outweighs direct savings in waste
management, resulting in net external costs which compound
commercial losses in the private sector.
All of the recycling scenarios satisfy criteria for social
feasibility under the optimistic interpretation of external
4.
benefits in Hhich the cost of househola Haste separation
is negligible.
Economies of scale {i.e. savings in money outlays due
to efficiencies inherent in ·larger scale operations) as
a result of increased participation would be substantial.
However, even under conditions in which community parti-
cipation in material recovery is 25 times greater than
estimates of current Anchorage participation (less than
1 percent), commercial feasibility would not be obtained
under basic scenario assumptions.
Thus, in addition to community participation in waste separation and
recovery, the product mix is itself an important determinant of commer-
cial feasibility. Individually, the cost of collecting, processing, and
shipping glass, mixed scrap paper, and corrugated containers (CC) would
exceed revenue potential. However, in contrast to mixed scrap and CC,
glass exhibits greater external benefits for each ton recovered than·
commercial losses per ton. Thus, from the standpoint of social feasi-
bility, glass recycling under 25 percent participation in the basic
scenario would be socially desirable.
A prominant, Seattle-based waste paper dealer recently commented
that, "The city is a forest to be harvested daily for its fiber content"
(Sid Shapiro, President, Paper Fibres Corportion). The preceding analysis
suggt!slts LhaL !:luu::;Laull<ill uuLup_bJc:J. re~ervee of several types of .secondary
materials are available for recovery in Anchorage. Further, the analysis
of existing circumstances in Anchorage's recycling recovery sector suggests
~hat it would be socially desirable to expand the scope of material re-
covery, but commercially prohibitive to do so under many circumstances.
Legislative initiative is therefore required to stimulate private and
public sector involvement in material recovery for recycling.
Several policy options are available to the state, including those
that are directed toward the recycling recovery sector (i.e. collectors
and recyclers) and those that affect community participation directly.
xi
[
[
[
[,
[
[
[J
tJ
F'
L
1:
b
n u
H
L
Direct subsidy. At one extreme, the subsi~y could consist of a
large grant to a single recipient. The major reasons for a subsidy of
this type are to concentrate funds to allow for a larger, more efficient
scale of recovery and, more importantly, to provide financial support
for materials that are socially beneficial but commercially unprofitable
to recover. The grant could be made contingent upon the recycle center's
acceptance of a carefully specified product mix. A policy of this type,
however, discriminates against the independent, unsubsidized collector
and potentially displaces private investment.
To reduce (but not eliminate) the discrimination problem, the state
could issue smaller grants to several local operations .. A small-grants
program, however, may not provide the financial relief required to achieve
cost-effective scale economies in less profitable materials. Thus, a
program of this type may increase the aggregate level of recovery with-
out altering the mix of materials to include less profitable grades.
Central recovery wholesaler. As an alternative to direct subsidiza-
tion, the state could fund a publicly operated, central processor/wholesaler
that intermediates between local, independent collectors and "stateside"
secondary materials dealers and specializes in processing (i.e. shred-
ding, crushing, baling, and compacting) and in shipping large quantities.
Although scale economies from consolidating recovery are not likely to
compensate for the recovery wholesaler's ongoing operating expenses, a
subsidized and stabilized price level would improve commercial prospects
.for local collectors and, therefore, stimulate additional recovery
effort.
Tax relief. Depletion deductions and tax credits provide indirect
financial incentives to recyclers and help to counter-balance existing
tax regulations that encourage over-production of virgin resources at
the expense of available secondary materials. Tax regulations do not
discriminate among recyclers and may be designed to integrate all or
some of the anticipated net social benefits. As in the case of dispersed
subsidies, however, tax relief would most likely ·stimulate additional
xii
recovery of secondary materials that already exhibit profits and not
address the equally important problem of socially beneficial but com-
mercially unprofitable material recovery. Tax relief may best be used
as an ancillary proposal in conjunction with other more direct recycling
policies.
Community participation. The success or failure of recycling depends
ultimately on the degree of residential and institutional participation
in separation of recyclable materials from nonrecyclable waste. While
"buy-back" policies (cash rebates) provide direct incentives for con-
sumers to recycle, the overall effect on the rate of participation is
unclear. For example, Seattle Recycling, Inc., (SRI) and Portland
Recycling Team (PRT) are relatively large, full-line recyclers with
comparable volume and composition of material recovery. In contrast to
SRI, which operates under a comprehensive buy-back policy, PRT depends
on consumer donations and on average achieves a compatible rate of
participation.
Compulsory measures may be combined with economic incentives to
further stimulate material recovery. For example, the office paper
collection scenario in Part IV demonstrates that a comprehensive program
in separation and collection of high-grade ledger paper from state and
municipal offices would release significant reserves of high-value waste
paper, reduce municipal waste management costs, provide supplemental
income to offices, and be well-received by local collectors. In addi-
tion to important economic advantages in both the private and public
sectors, a program in office paper separation would demonstrate positive
intent on the part ,.of the state (and the municipality) to get invO'lved
in recycling and would be an example that would precipitate involvement
elsewhere in the community.
Returnable beverage container legislation (RBCL) establishes a
mandatory deposit on most beverage bottles and cans and requires dis-
tributors and grocers to redeem, from customers, beverage containers
which they normally handle. The effect of RBCL depends in part on the
xiii
[
[
[
c
I; []
[
IJ ~
r l_;
h
L
r
I
L:
['
L
r u
[
1:
E
D
p
L
existing structure of a community's recycling recovery system. For
example, in \•:'ashington State, v.rhere RBCL is not in effect, revenues
from refillable bottles and cans represent the economic foundation on
vihich the decentralized system of independent, full-line recyclers
depends. The Hashington State Recyclers Association (i\'SRA) claims that
RBCL similar to Oregon's "bottle bill" would redirect important revenue-
generating bottles and cans away from independent, full-line recyclers.
Recent trends in Oregon's recycling recovery system suggest that RBCL
encourages large-scale, specialized recovery that focuses exclusively on
bottles and cans.
In Alaska, where proximity and handling constraints prohibit com-
mercial glass recovery by smaller, independent collectors and recyclers,
RBCL ":ould provide an institutional framework that vJOuld encourage the
development of more efficient techniques in handling and processing glass.
The public policy response to a large, unexploited reserve of second-
ary materials must be tailored to circumstances and problems unique to
Alaska c.nd to the domestic recycling industry as a ,,rhole. Distant prox-
imity to secondary materials markets is the primary constraint to the
development of recycling recovery systems in Alaska. On a broader scale,
the domestic recycling industry is sensitive to events which create even
slight changes in technology and in the relative value of secondary
materials. Therefore, policies must be carefully designed to avoid
.regulatory and institutional impediments that compete with and discrim-
inate against independent recyclers in the private sector.
Also, factors that are not readily expressed in economic terms,
such as aesthetics from litter and pollution reduction, should not be
overlooked as important qualifications to economic criterion for feasi-
bility analysis and for public policy evaluation.
xiv
[
INTRODUCTION [
The purpose of this study is to assist the House Finance Committee
of the Alaska State Legislature and other interested parties in the c
development of public policy to strengthen private and public sector
involvement in recycling. Funding for this research was made available
by the Rouse Finance Committee. [
A bill for an act related to " ... Comprehensive Recycling and [
Litter Reduction ... " (HB 5) is under consideration in the 1980 session
Alaska State Legislature. The bill is intended to initiate programs in
litter prevention and to encourage private and public recycling efforts.
The bill calls for the creation of a state agency to "encourage, organize,
and coordinate" public and private involvement in litter reduction, source [
separation, and recycling. The bill would also establish an advisory
council consisting of seven members to be appointed by the Governor. The
council would be responsible for furnishing guidance and encouraging the
participation of industry, labor, federal, state, and local government
agencies and the general public in recycling.
In its present form, the only definite actions taken in HB No. 5
r-:
El
are to establish litter prohibitions and to create an anti-litter symbol.
The remaining contents call for ex-pansion of state bureaucracy to "coordinate"
and to "encourage" litter prevention and recycling participation. Yet, a
well~defined task outline or institutional framework to achieve these
goals is not specified.
To some extent, the lack of specificity of H~ no. 5 reflects a
shortage of information regarding recycling feasibility and options
for stimulating litter reduction and recycling. In order to develop
positive, uniform legislation to achieve higher rates of material
recovery, further information regarding the potential for recycling
B waste products is needed.
[
The intent of this research is to develop an understanding of the
[ problems and constraints in Alaska's urban economic environment and in
the recycling industry as a whole that are responsible for the relatively
negligible public and private sector participation in recycling exhibited
in Alaska;
r The format of this research is divided into four analytical parts,
followed by a discussion of policy options. Part I presents a general
overview of the United States' recycling industry structure and highlights
technical and institutional factors that influence the market value of
recyclable materials and the extent to which recycling takes place.
In Part II our attention focuses on recycling potential in Anchorage.
I estimate how much waste material is feasibly recoverable from the
total quantity of a selected range of commodities that enter the Anchorage
economy for final consumption. Important features of market demand are
presented for specific secondary materials (i.e., used materials that
may be recycled as substitutes for primary raw materials) in order to
2
[
determine the compatability of recoverable supply and demand. Part II
also includes a description of the structure and cost of solid waste
management in the Anchorage municipality. He are particularly interested
in the effect of recycling on the cost of solid waste management. c
Note that an in-depth analysis of the supply and demand for recycled
commodities must focus on specific materials within a well-defined [
location. Considerable detail would therefore be required to accurately
analyze recoverable waste products at the state level. In many instances, [
data was missing or inaccurate and had to be estimated. In order to
retain a manageable level of detail, I have limited the scope of the
analysis to Anchorage and have confined the range of materials to tin n
Li
cans, aluminum, glass, and several grades of waste paper. The analysis
is therefore not intended to address the question of statewide recycling [
potential. Nevertheless, Anchorage constitutes a substantial proportion
of statewide economic activity and offers a reasonable study area for an
analysio of urban r0cycling potantial.
Part III examines the organization of recycling activity in Anchorage
and compares the present extent of Anchorage-based recycling with feasible
levels (for various materials) calculated in part II. The objective in
Part III is to estimate the average rate of recycling in Anchorage and
to establish a setting within which policy may apply.
We combine the information compiled in Parts II and III with relevant ~
L
data from specific ongoing recycling operations on the Pacific West Coast
3
to construct a set of expanded recycling scenari~s in Part IV and to
evaluate the costs and benefits of each. We paid particular attention
to the 11 hidden11 costs and benefits not captured in market relations, but
_j nevertheless, relevant to a comprehensive evaluation of recycling paten-
tial. Additionally, the sensitivity of recycling potential is examined
in connection with user buyback policies and changes in product mix.
In Part V, we review factors that limit recycling potential in
Anchorage and discuss the impact of a specific set of policy proposals
designed to stimulate the rate of recycling.
_j
~
'-l
d
' --=
:3
h
~:--~-~ .._.
~ 1;3
Q
0
f:d l~
E
c 4
PF_RT I. RECYCLING: CONCEPTS M~D ISSUES
'\\That is Recycling?
The basic principle of recycling is reuse. However, in contrast to
reuse, recycled materials are typically transformed into products that
do not necessarily retain their original identity.
Recycling may be divided into two phases. The first phase, designated
"material recovery," diverts solid vmste materials from permanent disposal
or dispersion. In the recovery phase, solid waste materials (such as used
newspapers, beverage containers, and tin cans) are collected and separated
into homogeneous categories or grades. In many cases, separation occurs
prior to collection. For example, household waste products may be separated
into specific categories directly after final consumption in preparation
for collection or delivery to the recycle center. This technique, known
as "suuu;.c t:.H:Oparntion," aid5 the efficiency of material rc.covcry by
preventing used materials from being mixed at the source of waste crea-
'tion and represents the principle method of household participation in
recycling.
Once recovered, secondary materials of a given grade and composition
are allowed to accumulate in a storage facility or recycle center warehouse
until sufficient mass is generated to raise total value to make further
processing and transportation economically feasible. Collectors then
sell recovered waste products to brokers or directly to secondary mater-
ials users.
5
[
[
·[
[
r
·D
[
[
n u
~-i
L
Host recovered materials undergo some form of second-phase "reprocessing"
[
depending on the degree of contamination and the nature of secondary use.
In the second phase of recycling solid waste materials are
reconditioned to eliminate additional contaminants and to isolate
desirable physical properties needed for a particular reuse application.
L
Reprocessing usually occurs at the location of reuse, where secondary
materials are manufactured into recycled commodities.
[
For example, waste paper fibers are separated from the original
product by mechanical agitation in a water slurry. Waste paper may
(l undergo additional treatment to remove ink (deinking) and other chemical
u contaminants. Generally, waste paper is broken down into fiber which is
[ then remilled into a lower grade of paper. Each "iteration" of recycling
reduces fiber size, and therefore, the quality of subsequent paper output.
In Alaska, pulp mills produce woodpulp, the first product category
in the sequence of paper making operations using virgin resources. Wood
pulp is then marketed to West Coast and Japanese paper mills.where various
basic paper grades are manufactured. Thus, "final" paper products are
not produced in Alaska. Because the pulping segment, which comprises
Alaska's paper industry, technically precedes paper milling operations,
there is no effective local market for waste paper fiber.
In contrast to paper, glass manufacture is a fully integrated,
one-step process which begins with basic raw materials and ends with. the
6
finished product at the same location. Cullet (bFoken glass) that is
color separated and contaminant free (especially of metal components)
may be used in place of raw material inputs (including sand, limestone
and soda ash). Because it melts at lower temperatures than raw materials,
cullet reduc.es furnace fuel consumption and air pollution emissions, and
increases the life of furnace linings. The utilization of cullet varies
widesly from 8 to 100 percent, by weight. Northwest Glass Co. in Seattle
currently uses about 30 percent cullet. Increases beyond 30 percent
reduce the manufacturer's control over final product viscosity and
coloration.
The Benefits of Recycling
By recognizing value in materials previously considered valueless,
the recycling industry _increases the stock of resources and introduces
three types of benefits into an economy:
1. Recycling waste materials conserves energy and natural
resources.
2. Recycling decreases the potential for environmental damage
connected with extraction of primary materials and with
landfill disposal.
3. Recycling reduces the volume of waste material that is
thrown away and thereby extends landfill life and reduces
solid waste management costs in processing and disposal.
7
[
r Lj
-[
c
L
"
[--
'
r
LJ
[
.
[
[
[
[
[
p
L
t:
Because waste materials retain a portion of the industrial energy
used in the original stage of manufacturing, the amount of energy needed
to process a unit of virgin ore exceeds the energy required to reprocess
an equivalent amount of recycle~ product from scrap material. Energy is
required to ship secondary materials from Alaska to west coast markets.
However, containers are backhauled whether or not they are loaded. The
extra energy cost of shipping a loaded over an empty container is negligible.
Thus, backhauling used materials requires essentially no additional energy
and instead makes better use of energy already encumbered in the transport
network. Consequently, I ignore the cost of energy consumed for backhauling
containers of secondary materials. A comparison of energy requirements
is presented in Table 1-l for selected commodities.
Table l-1 Energy Used in Processing Virgin
and Recycled Materials
Steel
Aluminum
Copper
Glass Containers
Plastics
(polyethylene)
Newsprint
Energy Needed to Process:
Virgin Ore Recvcle~ Material
(Btu/pound)
8300 7500 (40% scrap)
4400 (100% scrap)
134700 5000
25900 1400-2900
7800 7200
49500 1350
11400 8800
Source: Hayes, 1978, p. 17.
8
Amount of Energy
Saved by
R<"~Yd ing
(percent)
10
47
96
88-95
8
97
23
In general, the benefits of recycling follow from the reduction in
raw material processing and in the quantity of waste for collection,
processing, and disposal.
With the exception of ene~gy savings, these benefits are largely
unrecognized in the commercial system. The full environmental costs
created by pollution and waste generation are not readily measurable by
traditional economic accounting methods and therefore do not show up as
a cost of production using primary raw materials. Similarly, environ-
mental savings created by substituting recyclable materials for primary
raw materials and thereby foregoing additional pollution and waste
generation are not captured in market prices. As a result, secondary
materials used to produce recycled commodities are undervalued and
underutilized relative to virgin resources. The extent of under utili-
zation is not clear although Hayes (1978) claims that the average rate of
recycling1 is far belo•,T \.Jhat is attainable ,,dthout disrupting modern
standards of living. The data in Table 1-2 suggest that despite signi-
ic.-nt ~nvironm'"ntal and economic benefj ts frnm rPryrl in£, thP rwrrPntA£,P
of materials recycled nationwide is small.
Table 1-2 Recycling Rates for Selected Commodities
(Percent)
Paper
Glass
Aluminum
1967-683
18.6
4.2
18.3
3 Durnay and Franklin, 1972.
bEPA, 1975
1973-74b
18.4
3.0
17.0
1979
24 (newsprint
csid Shapiro, President, Paper Fibers, Inc., Seattle, Washington
dPeter ~~ited, District Manager, Recycling, Reynolds Aluminum
1 The average recycle rate is equal to:
9
tonnage recycled annually
average tonnage available
for recycling.
.c only)
[
c
,-,
L_j
[
[
r
L
B
G
H
L
-~
i
i L~
Institutional Constraints
In part, the structure of the national economy is itself responsible
for modest recycling activity .. The technology of industrial and consumer
goods production, and the composition of commodity demand, is geared
toward the use of virgin resources rather than secondary materials. The
secondary materials industry, in comparison with the more established
and often highly concentrated extraction and primary goods manufacturing
sector, is characterized by many small, specialized firms which compete
vigorously for stable, higher quality secondary materials supplies as
well as sources of regular industry demand. In addition to concentration
of o"mership, primary extraction industries exhibit a high incidence of
vertical integration2 through various levels of product fabrication.
Consequently, the extractive sector realizes a competitive advantage
over the recycling sector in terms of economies of scale (concentration)
and greater control over raw material inputs to production (vertical
integration).
The extraction sector is also supported by a tax structure which
encourages the production of virgin resources at the expense of recycling
available secondary materials. Tax deductions available exclusively to
the extractive sector include depletion allowances, the expensing of
intangible outlays for exploration and development, and capital gains
treatment on profits from appreciation of standing timber land.
2 Fer example, nearly all wood pulping operations are integrated
backward to include harvest and forward to include paper grade production.
Alaska pulp mills are not integrated forward and represent an exception
to the above statement.
10
Several technical features particular to secondary materials limit
the extent to which they may be recovered, reprocessed and reused
co~1ercially. They are:
1.
2.
3.
Contamination
Hass
Accessibility
As components of mixed solid waste, secondary materials are rarely
free of contaminants. The degree of contamination determines the
amount of handling effort required to collect and sort recyclables.
For example, the advent of bi-metal cans requires special magnetic
separation devices to remove ferrous materials from aluminum recovery.
Carbonless reproductive paper contains a non-soluble chemical
coating that cannot be removed by filters in the initial "hydropulping"
stage of waste paper reduction. Left unchecked, these contaminants
severely reduce the quality of recycled paper forcing costly mill shut-
dO'v.'D.S to clean equipment. Thus, considerable sorting is required by
the collector to remove undesirable chemical contaminants from higher
grades of wast~ paper.
The unit value of secondary materials increases with their mass.
As a result, baling and compacting are important functions to the overall
economies of recycling. Economies of scale (i.e. savings in money outlays
due to efficiencies inherent in larger scale operations) linked to second-
stage reprocessing of dense, homogeneous quantities of secondary materials
are sometimes passed back to the collector in the form of higher unit
prices that secondary material users are willing to pay for highe~ mass
11
[
L
[
[
1-J
bJ
LJ :
h L
_j
_j
r
[
n
Li
r
volumes traded. Moreover, increasing the density of recovered waste
products tends to lower the unit cost (cost per ton) of handling and
transportation. Thus, greater compaction reduces collection and trans-
portation costs, thereby raising the "netback" value the recycler
receives wh~n he sells secondary materials.
Accessibility of secondary materials is largely a function of the
degree of dispersion or the spacial distribution of consumption and
waste generation as well as the location of manufacturing operations
.. h d . 1 3 Whlc use secon ary materla s. In contrast to relatively concentrated
natural resources, secondary materials are generated in dispersed patterns.
Greater dispersion reduces the collector's control over the quantity and
regularity of material recovery. The recycle center which relies heavily
on the residential sector is unable to directly control resident participation
in material recovery. The recycler can only influence material recovery
through educational programs, collection strategies and buy-back policies.
On the other hand, commercial users generate higher, more regular
concentrations of secondary materials.
Once established, community involvement iu wasLe seJ..>alaLiuu autl tlelive.ry
is difficult to arrest. This was the experience of the Alaska Genter for
the Environment's (ACE) earlier newspaper collection program. In this case,
3 This is particularly relevant to Alaska. For example, aluminum cans
dispersed throughout Anchorage must first be consolidated into fea"sible
supply and then distributed to markets outside of Alaska.
12
collected newsprint was recycled locally into cellulose insulation (see
discussion of Thermo Kool below). h~en local demand for used newsprint
dissipated following seasonal demand contraction, ACE was forced to·
terminate its collection effort. However, residents continued to deliver
supplies to dispensed drop-off locations for a substantial period thereafter.
In this example, the absence of an adequate feedback mechanism to commu-
nicate market information to the consumer is partly responsible for
persistent newsprint deliveries.
The uniform nature of established community involvement in recovery,
a seemingly stabilizing force, can also reduce the responsiveness of
supply, to changes in demand and prevent the collector from effectively
exploiting sudden and unexpected shifts in demand. In some cases,
dealers actively resist attempts to satisfy what they perceive to be
irregular or transient demand swings in order not to disrupt established
patterns of trade.
Irregular tlemand tends to exacerbate unstable price behavior caused
by the more general lack of supply control. As a consequence of limited
accessibility and dependence on community participation, the recycler
faces uncertainties in both supply and demand. It is this feature which
sets recycling apart from other forms of commercial enterprise which
have greater control over supply.
13
[
0
[
[
r
L
[
n
b
B .
-
D B
[
[ In summary, limited demand for secondary materials has traditionally
[ been identified as the principle deterent in the expansion of the recycling
industry. It is becoming increasingly evident that, although certain
benefits inherent in secondary materials are not reflected in market prices,
the demand for secondary materials is rising. Despite the availability of
substantial reserves of untapped scrap, a myriad of institutional and
technical factors limit both the recycler's control over and ability to
expand supply in response to rising demand.
[
R u
[
14
PART II. l'1ATERIAL THROUGHPUT
The purpose of Part II is to establish a data base for subsequent
analysis. In general, the term "throughput" refers to the amount of D
material put through a process or system. In our example, material
throughput refers not only to volume and composition of commodity movement,
but to patterns of consumption and disposal, as well. Commodity categories [
of particular interest to this analysis include tin cans, aluminum cans,
glass containers and several grades of waste paper. I revise inbound [
quantity estimates of specific commodities to reflect the portion that
is feasibly recoverable for recycling. The potential for recovery
depends on factors related to accessibility and contamination discussed n
L
above. I then compare feasible recovery (supply) to potential demand in
west coast secondary materials markets.
In addition to a discussion of commodity movement, recovery potential
and market demand, I briefly review the structure of maritime transportation
between Anchorage and Seattle, paying close attention to factors that limit
flexibility in the determination of commodity tariffs. D
Finally, an overview of solid waste management in Anchorage is presented
to identify the elements of waste management most likely to be affected by
recycling, and to provide a framework to evaluate the impact of recycling
on solid waste management costs.
p,
L
15
L
c
[
n Li
[
n c
N
L
Commodity Movement
In L'Lchorage., the cycle of material throug:l:l.put begins with irr:ported
co~rrrnodities rather than endogenous production and is c.ompleted 1··.Titl1
disposal at the landfill or roadside. As show~ in Table 2-1, a total
.fu1chorage pppulation (including Eagle River, Chugiak, Turnagain Arm and
military bases) of 202,101 was supported by about 991,000 tons of imported
goods or 4.9 tons per person during 1978. Mixed cargo alone amounts to
almost 3,000 pounds per capita. About 17 percent of total inbound
tonnage entered landfill and 1 percent was exported primarily as scrap
metal (see Part III). The remaining 813,000 tons are durable commodities
and commodities that generate negligible waste material (e.g., petroleum).
Table 2-1 Commodity Imports to Anchorage
(1978 and 1992)
Commodity Group Inbound Tonnage
Crude Petroleum, Chemicals,
retroleurn rroduct~
Ores and Hinerals, Coal, Cement
Primary and Fabricous Materials,
Hachinery and Vehicles
Hood and Paper
Food, Fish, and Farm Products
Mixed Cargo (Metal Products and
Household Goods)
TOTAL
Assuwptiuus:
aEstimates
bp . . roJeCtl.ons
Source: Gray, 1979.
16
(thousands of tons per year)
171 300
125 186
101 173
142 218
166 274
286 430
991 1681
Paper
The total quantity of paper products imported into the railbelt
region is divided into newsprint, paperboard and paper products not
elsewhere classified (NEC) for selected years in Table 2-2. Paperboard
includes a ?ariety of grades ranging from corrugated containers used .
for packaging to hard pressed board for construction. Paper and paper
products not elsewhere classified (NEC) include printing, publishing,
and computer paper.
Table 2-2
Ne>,Tsprint
1973 4048
1974 5503
1976 11564
1977 10488
Assumptions:
Railbelta Paper and Newsprint Imports
(tons)"
Paperboard Paper & Paper Products
4425 6310
7165 5346
11292 4514
4334 6916
al6-18 percent is for Fairbanks.
NEC Total
14,783
18,014
27,370
21,738
In general, the Y.7 est coast market for assorted secondary paper fiber
is steady, strong and large. Recent expansion in U.S. trade relations
with China and India implies an extra stimulant to west coast export markets
in secondary paper. The supply and price of pulp as well as general
economic conditions are principal determinants in cyclical variation in
wastepaper prices. Brokers (dealers) attempt to maintain supply continuity
in both grade and tonnage while responding to price variation.
17
[
[
n
LJ
[
n
8
!=;
L
F' __ t--
=
c
[
r
L
[
r: u
The price received by Alaska paperstock collectors depends, in
part, on the homogenity and density of shipments. Genere.lly, it is best
to ship single item, high density loads although homogeneous, low density
shipments may still receive a high price. Mixed loads (e.g. half newsprint
and half computer print out (CPO) in a single container) require extra
handling to either broker or buyer which will be reflected in the selling
price.
Newsprint. Newsprint is the most abundant waste paper product in
Anchor,age. Two major Anchorage-based nev.•spapers have a combined de.ily
circulation of about 65,000, or 8,900 tons annually. However, local
competing uses for newsprint reduce the quantity available for collection
and marketing to \·;'est Coast paper stock brokers. For example, newsprint
is consumed as fuel and is used as a principal ingredient in the fabrication
of locally produced cellulose insulation (see discussion of Thermo Kool
1 below). According to Sid Shapiro of Paper Fibers, Inc. in Seattle,
local demand for newsprint lowers the "market" recycling rate in Alaska
substantially below the current U.S. average of 24 percent. Abstracting
from seasonal patterns in local newsprint demand, I assume that the
quantity of net..rsprint readily available for export to west coast recyclers
is equal to 50 percent of inbound quantity.2
1 Burning newsprint represents energy recovery and is therefore
technically different from material recovery for recycling. Combustion
uses the biological energy in paper fiber whereas recycling reuses the
industrial energy embedded in paper from the first round of production.
2 This is consistent with the observation in GAAB (1973) that newsprint
comprises about 10 percent of waste paper quantities disposed in "municipal
landfill" from residential sources.
18
Approximately 18 percent of newsprint fiber recovered nationwide is
recycled back into "new" ~ewspaper. The remainder is recycled into
lower grade paper products, including box board and construction paper.
The price of "catchweight11 newsprint bundles (packed in grocery bags or
bundle with twine, not baled) delivered in Seattle is currently (March
1980) $70 per ton. It is up from $60 in late November, 1979. In June,
1973, ne\,7 Sprint sold for $20 per ton in west coast markets. Newsprint
is generally more seasonal than other waste products, experiencing
shorter supply in winter months. A major Seattle recycler expects the
newsprint market to remain strong through August, 1980.3
Corrugated Containers (CC). A large quantity of corrugated containers
enter the ~1chorage economy as packaging for food products, household
goods, and general cargo. In some cases, retail outlets that ship
regularly backhaul used CC in empty southbound trailers. One Anchorage-
based grocery chain bales CC before it is hauled away by municipal
4 refuse collectors.
On average, corrugated containers comprise between 40 and 70 percent
(PRT, 1975, p. 28) of retail wastes. In Anchorage, 25 percent of waste
paper entering municipal landfill is CC. However, CC is a high bulk
commodity and requires considerable compacting for cost-effective trans-
portation. Thus, precrushing is necessary before baling and adds to overall
3 Don Knease, President of Seattle Recyclers Association.
4 Baled CC must then be broken do~~ before entering the shredder
at the municipal resource recovery facility (see discussion of solid
waste management below).
19
[
c
[
[
r~
L
[
r
b
h
L
[
c
n
L
C
b
p,
l
handling costs. Also, in mid-1979, the Japanese developed a process to
manufacture CC from newspaper. Consequently, a major segment of export
demand disappeared resulting in dm,7ll1''a..rd pressure on CC prices. Never-
theless, the Seattle price of baled CC rose from $80 to $100 between
November 1979 and March 1980.
High-Grade Paper Stock. High-grade waste paper consists of white
and colored ledger, computer print out (C~O), and IBM tabulating cards
(tab cards). Ledger is generated primarily from professional technical
and business offices. In 1978, there were approximately 29,000 non-
military employees in federal, state and local government, transportation-
communication-public utilities, and finance-insurance-real estate jobs.
Under the assumption that 3.4 percent of total wastepaper disposal is
office paper (GAAB, 1973, p. VIII-17), the total quantity consumed in
1979 from Anchorage users is about 3,070 tons or .75 pounds per day per
office employee.·
An unknown percentage of office waste paper includes "mixed file"
paper which is contaminated with insoluble chemicals, glue, carbon pa~er,
~nd plastic. The high grade component is most conveniently recovered
through office source separation techniques, accompanied by modifications
in janitorial services to handle recyclable and non-recyclable paper wastes.
For example, a prototype program in office paper source-separation
was conducted at the State Office Building in Juneau, in Spring 1979.
Office employees were encouraged to physically separate white ledger,
20
CPO, and tab cards from other components of office waste. Routine
janitorial services were modified (without increasing total labor time)
to handle recoverable component separately from other waste and deliver.
it to a convenient storage location for daily collection by the recycler.
Although several logistics problems regarding office participation and
the structure of janitorial services were encountered, program results
indicate that modifying janitorial procedures was relatively simple. In
this particular case, prior to the introduction of the office paper
separation program, the janitor contracted to transfer office wastes
from the building to the landfill site. The reduction in waste volume
from recycling reduced the number of required trips to the landfill and
resulted in potential net economic gains to the janitor.
Compared with other grades, the volume of high-grade office ledger
traded is less although the market value of high-grade is stable and not
expected to decline. Table 2-3 displays west coast prices for assorted
high-grade waste paper products and for less valuable mixed file paper.
Table 2-3 West Coast Paper Prices
West Coast Price
November 1979 Harch
White ledger
Colored ledger
CPO
Tab cards
Mixed file paper
Assumptions:
100-140
100-110
210
250
20
aHigh-grade products are 95 percent contaminant-free,
baled or bundled.
180
NA
235
270
50
1980
Source: Sid Shapiro, President, Paper Fibers, Inc., Seattle, Washington.
21
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
-
r
b
l=:::
L
r~
CPO and tab cards are consumed in commercial institutions, in all
levels of government, and in military offices as sho•~ in Table 2-4.
However, only a modest portion of CPO is feasibly recoverable due to
an increasing incidence of non-soluble chemical coatings and of carbon
paper. In-house record keeping and restrictions due to classified infor-
mation (especially in military CPO) further limit potential CPO recovery.
On the otherhand, the information on tab cards is typically transferred
to computer tape so that, although not an abundant source of recyclable
paper, inbound tab cards are 95 percent recoverable. Returning to Table 2-3,
v-1e note that tab cards and CPO represent the highest grades of waste paper
fiber commercially available.
Glass
The amount of container glass consumed and generated as waste material
is tied closely to food and beverage consumption. For example, in 1979,
more than 10 million 5 gallons of beer alone entered the Alaska economy.
. 6
Of this, I estimate that 4.5 million gallons entered Anchorage packaged
in 48 million 12·ounce aluminum cans and glat<;5 1utlles. TlH! ul~:>Lll1uLluu u[
glass and aluminum containers is approximately 41 and 59 percent, respectively. 7
Thus, about 20 million bottles of beer packaged in more than 6 million
pounds (3,000 tons) of glass were consumed in 1979. However, according
5 Bob Stevenson, Alaska Department of Revenue.
6 I assume that 50 percent of beer inbound to Alaska is consumed
iii Anchorage, and deduct 10 percent of that amount to account for bulk
containers.
7 According to Peter Hhited, District Manager for Reynolds Aluminum Co.
in Seattle, 3 million pounds of aluminum cans (about 66 million cans) entered
the Anchorage beverage market, of which 43 percent contains beer.
22
Table 2-4 Inbound Computer Print Out and IBM TAB cards for 1979.
(The Percent of Feasible Recovery of Inbound Tonnage is in Parenthesis)
(Tons)
Commercial Institutions and State Agencies
Municipal Offices
Military
Federal Offices
Total Inbound Tonnage
Recoverable Portion of Inbound Tonnage
Assumptions:
IBM TAB
CARDS
25
(95)a
20
(95) a
228b
(95)a
273
259
CPO
118
(38)c
1400
(38) c
1050d
(2)
1480
(ll)e
4048
950
ainformation on cards is eventually transferred to tape such that few
cards are retained for record keeping.
b Includes some federal agencies.
c25 percent of CPO contAins rArhon or rArhonlP<;:S chemic~ls;; for copying.
Thus, 75 percent of inbound CPO is high grade recyclable. 50 percent
of all CPO is assumed to be retained for office records. Therefore,
.75 x .50= .38 is available for recycling under ideal conditions.
d90 percent CPO contains carbon or carbonless chemicals for copyi~g.
Thus, only 10 percent of CPO is recyclable. 85 percent of all CPO
is assumed to be retained for office records. Therefore, .10 x .15 .015
is available (or recycling from military offices.
e25 percent of CPO contains carbon or carbonless chemicals for copying,
85 percent retained for office records. Thus, .75 x .15 = .11 is avail-
able for recycling from federal agencies.
Sources:
1.
2.
3.
4.
Chuck Parkam, GSA Customer Services Representative.
Bill Miernyk, Account Representative, Moore Business Forms, Inc.
Mr. Ferguson, Data Processing Supplies of Alaska.
Municipal Data Processing Office.
23
[
[
[
[
r:
lJ
to national statistics on the breakdown of glass containers (Darnay and
Franklin, 1972, p. 71-2), beer comprises only one~fifth of total glass
container uses, the remaining four-fifths is used for food, soft drinks
and other products. Table 2-5 presents an end-use distribution of glass
containers as applied to Anchorage data.
The data in Table 2-5 indicate that a substantial quantity of used
container glass exists. The amount that is feasibly recoverable depends
in part on resident participation in source separation, since roughly
[ three-fourths of used container glass is generated from household consum-
ption. In contrast to other secondary materials, the potential for
glass recovery is also limited by special problems in both handling and
freight.
[ Used glass ·must be separated by color and crushed into cullet for
compaction. Also, metal components such as twist off cap rings and
decorative foil must be removed. This ·creates special handling and
storage requirements, which add to the cost of recovery. Glass is also
comparatively expensive to ship. Freight costs alone consume from 50 to
80 percent of revenue, depending on m~rket conditions. Because glass
companies refuse to off-load containers with stacked bottles or 55
gallon drums of color separated cullet, the collector must hire or
provide off-loading services at the glass manufacturing facility. An
alternative to this economically unacceptable option is to use open top,
gravel type trailers with hydraulic lifts for convenient dumping of
cullet. This too, presents logistics and storage problems in addition
to the high cost of specialized containers. The steady recovery of
24
Table 2-5 Glass Containers by End-Use in Anchorage
End-Use Category Percent a Annual Quantity
(tons)
Number of Containers
Food 31.5 5040 NA
Beverages 48.9 7824
Liquor 4.8
\\line 2.6
Beer 19.3
Soft drink 22.2
Other b
TOTAL
19.6
100.0
768
416
3088c
3552
3136
16000d
19.7 million
Assumptions:
aBased on percentage of total U.S; glass container shipments in
1970. (Percentage Distribution, Durnay and Franklin, 1972, p. 71-2.)
b Includes medical, cosmetic and chemical containers
cEased on assumption that each container weights 5 ounces on average
(Alaska Cold Storage Distributors).
dNote, the discrepancY-leetween total weight of glass beverage containers
[
L
c
p
L
[
r LJ
in Tables 2-5 ~nd 2-@ reflects presence of Eagle River, Chugiak, Turnagain
Arm and military base populations in Table 2-5 and not in Table 2~. The ~
figures in Table 2-5 may contain a large error component depending on the
validity of Table Note c.
lO
25
n u
n u
[
r~
L
cullet must be stockpiled (in, say, 55 gallon drums or preferably in
storage bins) until the container returns from its Seattle destination.
Also, the cost of returning a container must be included unless arrange-
ments to shi~ a commodity bound for Alaska (e.g. cement) could be
negotiated with a West Coast producer. These and other problems with
glass are examined in the context of specific examples below.
The demand for cullet is growing less rapidly than other secondary
materials. A large multinational glass manufacturer in Portland, ~vens
Illinois, offers $30 per ton for metal free, color sorted glass or
cullet. Northwest Glass Co. of Seattle is smaller than ~ens, consumes
250-300 tons of cullet per week, and receives all the glass it needs at
$20 per ton. A $10 freight premium is offered to collectors at distances
greater than 100 miles from the North\vest plant.
As a raw material substitute, glass cullet does not require major
process changes by industry, uses less energy, and creates less equip-
ment wear. However, sand and soda ash, limestone, and feldspar, the
principal raw material ingredients in glass production, are not expected
to be in short supply, in the near future, although location-specific.
reductions in resource grade may increase the cost of production using
raw materials and improve the competitive position of cullet.
26
8 Aluminum Cans
The annual quantity of aluminum cans in Anchorage is approximately
3 million pounds (1,500 tons) distributed'between soft drinks (57 percent)
and beer (43 percent).
Scrap aluminum is an extremely high grade secondary material. Its
value stems largely from substantial energy savings over production from
bauxite ore (Table 1-1). West coast aluminum producers accept all the
scrap aluminum they can get and actively pursue recycling campaigns
designed to increase the nation-wide aluminum recycling rate beyond the
current 30 percent. In some cases, 'aluminum can producers are willing
to lease shredding, ,baling and magnetic separating equipment to collectors
and recyclers.
Although aluminum prices are comparatively less sensitive to seasonal
factors, the export segment tends to reduce stability in prices. In Japan,
the demand for recycled aluminum exceed's the level of feasible domestic
(Japanese) recovery. Consequently, .Tap<=tn rAnnnt gPnPrAtP snffi ci Pnt
recovery from internal sources.
The affect of rising energy prices and strong international demand
creates upward pressure on scrap aluminum prices as well as positive
incentives for aggressive programs in aluminum recovery.
8 In addition to aluminum cans, scrap aluminum is generated from
aircraft components, furniture, construction materials, foil and other
packaging materials. See discussion of Stano Steel below.
27
[
c
n
[
r
Li
[
r
Li
n LJ
~
L
[
[
E
Buyers are currently paying upwards of 45 cents per pound
($900 per ton). This price has increased from about 35¢ in su~~er, 1979.
Tin Cans
9 The common "tin" can actuaily consists of a steel can coated
with tinplate. As premium metal products, both the tin and steel
components of recovered tin cans are separated by a chemical process
known as detinning. Tin producers are currently paying $7 per pound of
recovered tinplate.
Until recently, detinning of used steel cans was considered uneconomic,
because the detinning industry accepted only clean tinplate scrap from
industrial sources. However, household waste separation techniques '\.;rhich
remove organic, ~luminum (bimetals) and paper contaminants can produce
a marketable scrap tin product that lends itself to economic recovery and
detinning.
ln Seattle, detinning capacity can absorb more than 30,000 tons per
year of additional quantity.10 Tin cans delivered in Seattle receive
a current price of $78 per ton, up from $71 in November 1979.
'
9 The "tin" can is distinguished from the "bi-metal" steel cans
v,rith aluminum tops. Bi-metal cans must be shredded and the ferrous (steel)
portion removed magnetically.
10 Jack Force, President of M & T Chemicals, Inc., Seattle Washington.
28
The maximum quantity of tin cans available for recovery from resi-
11 dential source separation in Anchorage is estimated at 4,300 tons.
This represents about half of scrap ferrous metal generated from Anchorage
residential sources in 1979.
Plastic-s, textiles, organics and other miscellaneious waste materials
are excluded from this discussion of recycling. Although technically
possible, and energy-conserving, recycled plastic has negligible demand, re-_
fleeting limited reuse applications and underdeveloped markets. However,
should current trends in fossil fuel prices persist, the economics of
plastics recycling may become increasingly attractive. Plastics alone
constitute about 2 to 9 percent of the Anchorage waste stream. Textile,
rubber and tire wastes comprise an additional 3 to 4 percent. In 1979, wood
plastics, textiles, rubber, and leather amounted to 24,339 tons of mixed
. solid waste.
The impact of recycling and household source separation and on consume·r
product selection that encourage techniques in waste reduction, such as
standardized packaging.12 Waste reduction, an alternative encouraged "by the
[
[
[
[
[
11About 9 percent of total residential mixed solid waste in Anchorage is F:_-__ :
ferrous metal (Metcalf and Eddy, 1979) .. The pure tin content of all ferrous E3
metal in municipal solid waste is estimated at 2 percent (Darnay and Franklin,
1972). Thus, pure tin disposal from residential sources in 1979 is equal to
179 tons. The typical "tin" can is 4 parts tin and 96 parts steel, thus about G
4,300 tons of "tin" cans entered the Anchorage landfill from residential sources. B
12 Evidence of waste production fostered by the establishment of
a neighborhood recycling program in Berkeley, California is available in
PRT (1975, p. 43).
29 [ -.
--~
r
LJ
r~
L
r
L
~
L
recycling concept, is perhaps the most efficient solution to the high volume
of plastics, t-extile, rubber and other miscellaneous constituents in the
mixed ,,,-aste stream.
Note that for the food, fish and farm products commodity category in
Table 2-1, p~ckaging materials constitute approximately 41,500 tons (25 percent).
This is equivalent to more than 400 pounds per person annually in packaging
waste alone. Packaging material, of which plastics are a major component,
therefore, comprises 40-50 percent of household-generated mixed solid waste.
Table 2-6 summarizes the information regarding recycling potential
for selected secondary materials. Glass is the largest source of
technically recyclable material. However, comparison of market price
and freight costs indicate that glass is least favored of the materials
listed. From a preliminary economic standpoint, aluminum cans occur in
reasonable quantity (5 percent of total weight of potentially recyclable
materials) and offer the highest after-freight return. The annual total
quantity of all secondary paper products listed is 14,372 tons or 40 percent
of potential recyclables. Wastepaper prices range from $50 to $270 per ton
and are not expected to behave as cyclically as they have in the recent
past. Hith the exception of glaoo, mnrlccto for various rccycla.bl~s in
Table 2-6 are strong and are experiencing a phase of steady growth in response
to heightened foreign demand and to chronic woodpulp shortages in the
pacific northwest region.
In Figure 2-1, the inbound quantities of selected materials are
compared to estimates of recoverable tonnage in Table 2-6. Note that the
30
Table 2-6 Recovery Potential, Market Price and Freight Factor
For Selected Secondary Materials
[
Material a Recovery Potential
(tons)
Market Price (Seattle)
($/ton)
b[ Freight Factor J
($/ton)
High Grade Ledger
CPO
Tab cards
950
259
235
270
180 White ledger
Colored ledger
Mixed file paper
3070 NA
50
Newsprint 4450 70
Corrugated Containers 5643 100
Aluminum cans 1500 900 16.00
Tin cans 4300 73 16.00
Glass 10,085 30 16.00
TOTAL 30,257
19 % 1979 Solid Waste
Assumptions:
aAll products should be free ot contaminants especially high grade white
and colored ledger. White and colored ledger, mixed file paper, and
CC are all baled; CPO tab cards bundled; and newsprint neatly stacked.
Aluminum cans are shredded, flattened or baled. Organic and papeT
contaminants removed from tin cans; bottoms removed and cans .flattened.
Glass is crushed and color separated.
hFreights assume,a 40-by 8-by 8.5-foot standard size
trailer for all secondary materials.
cVariation in wei.ght per volume considered negligible. In all cases,
paper density is such that container reaches Interstate Commerce Commission
(ICC) weight limits before reaching volume capacity of container.
dDensity of baled CC is low. Here a 40 foot container can hold 10
tons maximum. Note, a 27 foot container holds 6.75 tons. However,
higher tariff per ton is charged for smaller load size. Tariff
for 27 foot container is equal to $75.89 per ton.
31
c
[
[
n
L..l
[
~
L
c
c
I ,
L
n
L
c
b
D . .
s:::: L
inbound quantity o·f tin cans is estimated indirectly from municipal solid
waste data. In contrast to tin cans, the recoverable component of
paper, glass and aluminium cans falls short of respective inbound quantities.
For paper, glass and aluminum, the gap between inbound and recoverable
reflects the affect of contamination and of local reuse demand. Bimetal
cans which contain steel and aluminum components reduce the recoverable
portion of aluminum cans to half of pure plus bimetal aluminum cans.
Used tin cans are extremely pure and have few if any local
uses that compete with demand in secondary materials markets and are
assumed to fully recoverable.
Figure 2-1 Comparison of Anchorage Bowl Annual Inbound
and Recoverable Quantities for Selected Commodities.
(Tons)
Tons 22,000
20,000
16,000 Recoverable
Quantity
10,000
a Paper
10,085
alncludes military, CPO and tab cards.
3,000
1 . b A umJ.num
cans·
Tin cans
b Includes military, Eagle River-Chugiak and Turnagain Arm.
cExcludes military.
32
c.
[
The Structure of Transportation [
The potential for recycling in Alaska is strongly influenced by the c
cost of transporting secondary materials to destination markets. In general, [ transportation absorbs about 25_percent of gross revenue from the sale of
secondary materials. In some cases, freight costs alone are sufficient
deterents to commercial applications in secondary material recovery.
[
A key feature of commodity movement to and from Alaska is that
90 percent of southbound container capacity is unused. As a result, backhaul
[
revenues are not sufficient to cover the operating cost of southbound
movement.
For example, total backhaul from Anchorage to Seattle is equal to
90-100 thousand tons per year, or about 9 to 10 percent of forward and
backward tonnage. (See Table 2-7.)
Table 2-7 Breakdown of Backhaul Materials
and Kevenue Potential
Material
Household
Percent of Total
Backhaul
. (%)
43
Auto and Hachinery 17
Fish 20
Scrap and other metal 20
Approximate
Quantity
(tons)
43,000
17,000
20,000
20,000
100,000
Average Backhaul
Rate per 100 lb.
$5.20/100 lbs.
) $1.50/100 lbs.
source: John Gray, Assistant Professor in Transportation, Institute of
Social and Economic Research, University of Alaska, Anchorage.
33
n
L.;
[
r
b
BackhauO
Revenues
$4,472,oQ IJ
1,710,000
-----tg-
$6,282,000
B
r
_'
-.
[
[
p
L..l
[
D
The revenues generated from southbound commodity movement approximate
$6.3 million or about 6 percent of $100 million in total (forward and
backward) operating costs for both carriers combined. The amount of
used container capacity has a minor impact on overall freight costs.
Thus, the cost of southbound mov~ment is roughly equal to that of northbound.
Backhaul revenues from current tariffs therefore absorb about 12 percent
of southbound transport operating expenses.
Carrier's structure northbound tariffs to cover this southbound
deficit and, by doing so, effectively integrate the forward and backward
rate structure. Although the extra freight cost of shipping an otherwise
empty container is negligible, carriers are unlikely to lower backhaul
tariffs below current levels and further shift the burden of backhaul
d .r: • • hb d d. h. 13 e~lclt on nort oun commo lty s lppers.
One could argue that since a given container would be returned to
west coast ports empty and costs roughly the same to ship empty or full
(P?rrlnrling the cost of spotting), why not fill tho container (v;rith used
materials) and charge the shipper a tariff that he can afford? By not
doing so, the carrier foregoes an opportunity to earn extra income with-
out increasing costs. From the perspective of a single extra shipper
13 Note that carriers do give special consideration to organizations
shipping non-standard commodities that apply for tariff reductions. Note
also that tariffs are established by the carrier and approved by the
Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC). The ICC does not regulate or monitor
carriers. The ICC will respond to complaints to see that carriers do not
depart from tariffs. A uniform rate structure exists as a result of compe-
titive relations between carriers.
34
[
I
l~
c
[
b
r ~
[
this arguement is infallible. However, from the standpoint of aggregate
corrt111odity movement, the same policy applied indiscriminantly to all
secondary material shippers 1..rould lm,rer total backhaul revenues below
current levels and deepen the carrier's aggregate backhaul deficit. If
the ICC permitted carriers to charge lower backhaul rates (say, one half
of original levels) to only secondary material collectors, then annual
backhaul revenues would decline 50percent from $600,000 to $300,000,
under constant outbound secondary material recovery. Outbound tonnage
of scrap would have to increase 33 percent (10,000 tons) for carriers to
breakeven under lower scrap material backhaul rates 1v-ithout disturbing
northbound tariffs.
Some latitude in freight rates is available to shippers (i.e. a
recycle center) because of flexibility in rate implementation. The
tariffs vary depending on the vleight of the shipment; a larger load
receives a lower tariff. To a certain degree,.tariff reductions are
matched with the capacity of the container and the density of the parti-
cular material in order to encourage shippers to fill containers. Typical
container sizes are 27 and 40 feet in length.
The carrier charges the shipper either by container size or by the
net weight of goods shipped. Thus, it may be advantageous to the shipper
to us~_a partially filled 40 foot container and incur the 40 foot container
tariff, rather than filling a 27 foot container and incurring a higher
freight rate per unit of weight.
35
For example, we note from Table 2-8 that a 27 foot container has
a minimum weight of 30,000 pounds (15 tons) of wastepaper. A 35,000 pound
load is not sufficient to receive the lower tariff that applies to
42,000 pounds or more. Nevertheless, by shipping 35,000 tons in a 40 foot
container and receiving the 40 foot container tariff, the shipper pays
less per ton' than shipping 30,000 of the original 35,000 pounds at the
higher tariff of $34.15 per ton.
Table 2-8 Southbound Shipping Specifications for Waste Paper
Minimum Weight to
Receive Tariff
30,000 lbs.
42,000 lbs.
Corresponding
Container Size
27
40
Tariff
(per ton) (per container)
$34.15 $512
$26.93 $566
Source: Tariff Publishing Offices, Sea Land Service, Inc.
In general, carrier services covered in the southbound tariff included
spotting at the point of departure and destination. Thus, in addition to
shipping the container from departure to destination ports, the carrier will
pick up the loaded container at the shipper's location and deliver iL to its
destination provided these respective locations are within a specified com-
mercial zone. Thus, to some extent, the logistics of mobilizing recyclables
to" destination markets are subsumed in the rate structure and managed by the
carrier.
36
[
[
c
[
[
c
f'
r
b
~
L
n I ,
tJ
u
p
u
r=
C
r:
Solid Haste :Hanagement
In this section, I revieH the principal phases of municipal solid
-vmste management in Anchorage, including collection, processing and
disposal. I then identify the probable impact of recycling on each phase.
The quantity of waste disposal in Anchorage is closely linked to
population and the level of economic activity. Bet1veen 1972 and 1978,
the quantity of "'c.ste disposal nearly doubled from 94,380 to 168,330, tons.
Over that interval, the rate of per capita Haste generation increases. at
an average annual rc.te of 2 percent, reaching 5.45 pounds per capita per
day for non-military,14 Anchorage bowl residents (as shoHU in Table 2-9).
Table 2-9 Anchorage Bowl Waste Disposala
1972 1977 1978 1979
I.Jaste disposal 94380 158214 168330 160084
(tons)
Population 105320 160035 169269 170281
(bowl)
Mixed Solid Waste 4.91 5~42 5.45 5.15
per Capita per Day
Assumptions:
~aste quantity and population figures do not include Eagle River,
Chugiak, Turnagain Arm, and military residents.
Source: Planning Department and Division of Solid Waste,
Municipality of Anchorage.
14 The generation rate for military personnel is about 50 percent higher
than civilian.
37
From 1978 to 1979, the quantity of waste disposal "decreased 5 percent \vhile
population increased 1 percent. During this period, the rate of daily
per capita waste generation fell 6 percent to 5.15 pounds.
The composition of residential and commercial waste is broken do~~
into combustible and non-combustible material classifications in Table 2-10.
The material percentage distribution is based on recent Anchorage-based
surveys conducted by Hetcalf and Eddy (1979). The composition of Anchorage
refuse is generally consistent with that of other municipalities. Paper
and glass are slightly below the national average, whereas metals and
assorted debris exceed the average. (Quimby, 1975, p. 18).
Paper products constitute the largest component of mixed solid waste
in both residential and commercial classifications. Paper also comprises
almost 60 percent of total combustible materials.
Collection
Collection in the Anchorage bowl is carried out by the Hunicipal
Department of Public Works (DPW.) and by Anchorage Refuse Incorporated
(ARI), a private hauler. The military bases are responsible for their
own collection and disposal operations. The state Division of Parks· and
Recreation and the Environmental Protection agency (EPA) provide collection
services for special waste materials. Together DPW and ARI collect about
38
[
c
c
[
n
LJ
n
l
E .
'
w
lO
r--:--
1,_ j I j rn tliLl..r:ru
Nat erial
Combustible
Paper
Wood Plastics, Textiles
Rubber, and Leather
Garden Wastes
Total Combustible
Non-Combustible
Glass
Metal
Garbage, Ash, Dirt, Rock
Total Non-Combustible
Total
Assumpt:ions:
:----;
I., •. J
Table 2-10 Residential and Commercial Compositiona
of 1979 tvl:i.xed Solid Wastes
Classificat.Lon
Residential (62%)
49.9
9.2
6.5
65.6
7.0
10.5
16.9
3Lf, 4
100
9391
65109
69LI8
101+21
166 7Lf
34143
99252
67.0
25.0
NA
92.0
2.0
6.0
NA
8.0
100
15208
55965
1217
3650
4867
60832
a Data do not include Eagle River, Chugiak, Turnagain Arm, and military bases.
b Anchorage bowl population in 1979 was 170,427.
Totnl
%
15.2
4.0
75.6
5.1
8.8
10.5
24.4
100
9028/1
24JJ9
6451
8165
14071
16 77Lf
l .. LJ,I
160084b
Source: Metcalf and Eddy, 1979, Joel Grundwaldt, Director, Division of Solid ~vaste Hanagement, GAAB
63 percent of total mixed solid waste. For 1979, this was equal to
100,853 tons. The remainder of Anchorage \.Jaste is delivered to the
disposal site by citizens in private vehicles. In 1979, ARI collected
60,000 tons, mainly from residential subdistricts in the surrounding
bowl area, including Eagle Rive: and Chugiak. ARI currently retains
about $2 million in collection equipment. Operating expenses 15 are
estimated at $3.4 million, or about $57 per ton in 1979.
DPW is responsible for the remaining 40,853 tons of collected (as
opposed to delivered) mixed solid waste. Making 5,700 weekly pick-ups,
with eight, 3-cubic-yard dumpster trucks averaging 125 stops daily, DPW
services a total of 1850 dumpster containers in addition to primarily
single resident dwellings located somewhat more centrally than those of
ARI. DPW incurs operating expenses equal to $2.6 million, or about $64
per ton collected.
In 1979, about 120,000 private vehicles.delivered the remaining
59,231 tons, averaging 987 pounds per vehic-1 P.. Assnming An ~vG>r~E/?
roundtrip distance of 7 miles per vehicle, an average fuel economy of 10
miles per gallon at $1 each p1us one hour of labor time at $7 16 each,
gives a total private delivery cost of $924,000. Table 2-11 summarizes
the quantity and cost of collection for each alternative collectiorr
mode. Together, private citizens, ARI, and DPW collected 160,084 tons
at $6.9 million, averaging $43.25 per ton;
15 Cost estimates are taken from Alaska PUC tariff revision, TA7-217.
16 Second quarter 1979 wage rate in Anchorage.
40
[
[
[
[
r u
[
E
r~
Taole 2-ll .tulnual Total Cost of Refuse Collection in 1979
Collector Quantity Annual Total Cost Cost per Ton
(tons) ($) ($/ton)
Anchorage Refuse,
Inc. 60,000 $3.4 million $57/ton
Hunicipal Dept.
of Public \,1 orks 40,835 $2.6 million $64/ton
Private Citizen 59,281 $924' oooa $16/ton
Total 160,084 $6.924 million $43.25/ton
Assumptions:
aAssuming round trip distance equal to 7 mile at 10 miles per
gallon, plus ~hour labor time per trip: Thus:
84,000 ga. @ $1.00 ea
120,000 hours @ $7.00 ea
$ 84,000
840,000
$924,000
Note, vehicle maintenance and depreciation not included. Also, $7
implicit wage is based on average wage rate in Anchorage, second quarter,
1979. (Alaska Department of Labor, Statistical Quarterly, Second Quarter,
1972.)
41
Processing. and Disposal [
Once collected, mixed solid waste undergoes processing and disposal.
Until recently, processing consisted of the compaction that occurred in [
the course of spreading waste material over areas in municipal landfill
where·refuse was previously deposited. On average, the volume of waste
material compacted in this fashion is equal to about 800 pounds per square
foot.
[
Beginning in 1980, the Municipality of Anchorage modified waste [
processing by introducing "front-end" resource recovery. Rather than
entering landfill directly, mixed solid waste is first shredded, sifted,
magnetically separated, and air classified in order to increase the density
of refuse and to convert the combustible fraction of mixed solid waste n u
into a fuel supplement for burning in coal fired furnaces. [
The 1000 horsepower shredding plant, costing $4.5 million, can mill r:
LJ
up to 50 tons of refuse per hour, but does not burn refuse or generate
slcd.tu. PlauueJ uuL]JUL fuL 1980 i::; 157,800 Low~, wlLh;, pl·ojl"cteci $1.9 million
annual total operating cost. This reduces to $12.29 per ton and includes
the cost of transfer to the landfill site.
Under ideal conditions, resource recovery produces energy from refuse.
The energy byproduct, designated Refuse-Derived-Fuel (RDF), is generated
from air classification of lighter, more combustible components of mixed
solid waste (primarily paper, plastic, and wood scrap, although metal and
l=i
glass particles are notoriously difficult to exclude from RDF.) Recall from L
42
[
I
L
D
L
n
L;
[
F'
Table 2-10 that about 75 percent of mixed solid waste generated in
Anchorage is combustible.
RDF mc.y be "co-fired" \vith coal to generate steam for elec:.Lrlc: lJOvJet.
Prospectiv·e local markets are limited by technical considerations involving
equipment and facility conversion to accommodate restrictive RDF character-
istics. RDF has high moisture content and contains substantial non-combustible
elements which reduce efficiency, accelerate corrosion and contribute to
substantial pollution emissions (Lipshutz, 1979). In fact, numerous technical
difficulties have delayed progress in national development of resource re-
covery.
Between 1974 and 1978, nationwide capital investment in resource
recovery has exceeded $474 million with facility design capacity ranging
from 50 to 3000 tons per day. Of 23 resource recovery projects on line
or under development over this interval, 6 were able to realize marginal
success in marketing or burning internally generated RDF. Until markets
for RDF are established in Anchorage, all milled refuse is disposed in
the municipal landfill.
In contrast to recycling, which emphasizes material recovery,
resource recovery captures only the heat content of the waste material,
but in doing so, fails to take advantage of energy savings which could
have been realized by not 4aving to process virgin materials displaced
by recycled waste materials. Besides conserving for uses other than
disposal, resource recovery implies conservation only to the exte~t ,that
43
RDF displaces fossil fuels directly, whereas recycling not only conserves
materials, it conserves energy by reusing the energy content of recovered
materials.
However, it is unlikely that recycling will recover all mixed solid
waste, even' under conditions of maximum participation. For waste products
not recycled, resource recovery is capable of reducing refuse volume and
thereby reducing the volume of waste disposed of in the landfill.
The density of refuse milled in the shredding plant is increased
50 percent from 800 to 1200 pounds per cubic yard. As a result, an acre
of landfill space having an average depth of 10 feet (GA~B, 1973) can
absorb 9700 tons of milled refuse compared with 6500 tons of loose,
semi-compacted mixed solid waste. Under conditions of a constant stream
of future waste equal to 1979 levels, the shredder can increase the
longevity of remaining landfill capacity by 50 percent.
ID~teas Lesuutce L~cuvery (shredding) increases the density ot mixed
solid waste, and thereby adds to the quantity of refuse a given volume
of landfill may absorb, recycling reduces the actual quantity of mixed
solid waste intended for disposal. Despite important qualitative dif-
ferences, an ultimate effect of each process is to extend the life of
the l~mdfill.
The present landfill site encompasses 211 acres, of which 80 are
already filled, and services the entire Anchorage bowl, excluding military
44
[
[
[
c
[
[
n
L
[
r
b
n L
~
L
L
bases. The remaining 131 acres are projected to reach capacity in 1986.
The landfill site is situated adjacent to Herrill Field Hunicipal Airport
_j and is planned to accoliJJ.-nodate airport expansion after it is filled.
The impact recycling has on landfill costs depends on several factors,
including current waste disposal practices, land use alternatives, and
replacement costs associated with new landfill site development.
Figure 2-2 depicts the filled and unfilled portion of the municipal
landfill site and compares the 1980 assessed value of selected land
parcels in and adjacent to the landfill site (excluding buildings and
other improvements). The figures suggest that mixed solid waste enhances
property value in the landfill site. In fact, the assessed value of
[ completed landfill exceeds the value of both filled landfill property as
well as adjacent non-landfill property.
These results may reflect the combined effects of physical improve-
ments caused by dumping mixed refuse and raising the surface level above
the water table and of landfill space becoming available for alternative
uses sooner. Thus, from the standpoint of municipal airport expansion,
refuse disposal in landfill does not induce permanent damage, but enhances
property value, in part, by providing space for airport expansion.
Under these circumstances, recycling delays opportunities for
alternate land-use applications by extending landfill longevity. To
some extent> we may discount the costs associated with delayed implementation
45
> ro s: c
,.. ::J
r. 0:
..c
+-'
::J o·
(/)
I
..c
t
0 z
Figure 2-2. 1980 Assessed Value for Select Land Parcels
in or Near the Municipal Landfill Site
East-'Nest Runway
Teamster's Land
$37,539 per acre
1111111111 Landfill perimeter
Source: Municipality of Anchorage, Property Appraisal
~--1
l...-j
0> .::
0
II) ...,
..c
.':!"
<I>
I
t
0
0. ....
<(
__ _:;
c
b
~-
D .
.
of land-use alternatives (e.g. foregone airport tie do~m earings) to
reflect the 5 to 10 year interval required for settling. Also, the
landfill is not indivisible. Complete~ segments can be used for alter-
native purposes prior to completion and settling of the entire landfill
site.
The impact of recycling is probably most strongly felt in connection
with the long-run costs of developing new sanitary landfill locations.
Landfill sites in Anchorage (near the international airport), Eagle River-
Chugiak, and GirdHood have all terminated since 1978. Hith the exception
of military bases, ,,7 hich operate their mm landfill sites, all mixed solid
waste collected in the greater Anchorage area is now deposited in the
landfill site near Merrill Field. According to Joel Grunwaldt, director
of the municipa:l_ity's Division of Solid Waste, the only remaining "environ-
mentally acceptable" landfill site is located in a gravel pit near Sand
Lake.
The cost of developing alternate locations for waste disposal depends
primarily on phyisical characteristics at alternative landfill sites. The
l~vel of ground water in the vicinity of the site is a particularly impor-
tant consideration. In order to meet federal drainage and ground water
pollution requirements, the Sand Lake site will require impervious liners
d d b f . . f . 17 . h 1 to prevent ownwar su sur ace mlgratlon o contamlnants lnto t e re a-
tively low ground water table that characterizes the area. At a current
17 Note that leachate solutions generated from landfills have 200 times
the toxicity of raw sewage.
47
cost of $1 per square foot, it is likely that preparation of liners for
the Sand Lake location would exceed $1 million (Grunwaldt).
Landfill grading, access, fencing and equipment maintenance facilities
must also be considered in the determination of overall landfill development
costs. In general, the combination of increasingly restrictive pollution
controls, greater landfill distances from urban centers, and escalating
land values contribute to rapidly rising landfill operation and relocation
costs.
However, in the Sand Lake example, landflll replacement costs are
reduced to the extent that equipment and facilities may be transferred
from the old to the new site. Also, in its present condition, the Sand
Lake site has few competing uses, which lowers the potential for dis-
placing other land-use alternatives. Consequently, the land-use savings
implied by recycling pertain largely to the earnings that may be generated
from funds earmarked for landfill replacement over the interval that
landfill replacement is delayed.
If, for example, the cummulative effect of a recycling program over
a 5 year interval extends landfill life for six months (this implies recycling
program diverts about 16,000 tons per year from·landfill disposal) and
$3 million in funds earmarked for leachate liners, fencing, road construction,
and facility set-up are invested in 9.5 percent securities over that extra
half-year interval, then the savings of recycling, discounted to reflect
present value (at 9.5 percent), are equal to about $88,500 or $1.10 per
48
[
n
c
L
n
L
[
r
[J
p
ti
E
[:
'
~-..J
_ __j
r
b
15
8
r::
L
L
ton recycled. These savings would increase ,,rith an increase in the
projected replacement cost of the alternate landfill site.
In the discussions that follow, I ~sume that the cost of developing
an alternate landfill site at Sand Lake is $3 million in 1986, so that,
on average, each recycled ton of waste material \..rould save the munic;Lpality
$1.10.18 in 1980 dollars. I also assume that recycling has no affect on
property damage or improvement created by mixed solid waste disposal, nor
does recycling affect the opportunities for land-use alternatives at
the existing landfill. Thus, the net affect of recycling on landfill
operations is confined to savings realized through reduced pressure on
new site development.
The impact of recycling on the solid waste manag·ement system as a
Hhole are defined in terms of savings in processing and disposal, and in
landfill operations. I assume the impact of recycling on refuse collection
by ARI and DPW is negligible.
Further, there is no indication that RDF markets exist at this time.
Thus, the potential costs recycling imposes on the quantity or quality of
RDF is not considered.
18 Note that this result does not depend on the assumed rate of recycling.
A lower rate of recycling would extend the landfill life less, reduce the
delay time for new landfill development, and therefore, reduce the interest
earning potential of landfill development funds over the extension period.
However, by assumption, the quantity recycled is less. Consequently, savings
per ton recycled do not change.
49
Processing and dispoals costs are based on budget estimates for 1980.
In Table 2-12, the cost ~f disposal is divided into fixed and variable
components reflecting that category's sensitivity to changes in the quantity
disposed. These costs are based on planned disposal of 173,200 tons, of which
157,800 tons would be shredded.· Annual total cost per ton is equal to
. 19 $16.65; $10.73 is variable and $5.92 is fixed (operating and capital
7'7
recovery cost). The variable component is~ percent of annual total
operating cost. Thus, a ton of mixed solid waste diverted from processing
and landfill disposal saves $10.73 in direct processing disposal expenses.
Fixed expenses, by definition are not affected by tonnage reductions.20
Table 2-12 · Annual Total Operating and Capital
Costs for Processing and Disposal
Operating Cost
Variable
Fixed
Total Operating Cost:
Capital Recovery Cost
Annual Total Cost:
Assumptions:
1,858,410
552,980
$2,411,390
472,880 -
$2,883,870
aBased on 173,000 tons disposal.
a Cost/ton
10.73
3.19
2.7
16,65
Source: Processing and Disposal Fund, Financial Detail for the Division
of Solid Wastes, Department of Public Works, Municipality of
Anchorage. Joel Grunwaldt, Director, provided interpretive
assistance.
19
is equal
factors:
landfill
Note that the total cost of
to $12.29. The difference
(l) $12.29 includes fixed
is shredded.
shredding one ton of mixed solid waste
between $12.29 and $10.73 reflects two
costs, and (2) not all waste entering
20 Recycling may, in fact, delay or preclude future capital outlay
in both collection and disposal. We ignore this effect. Under the assump-
tion that in the near future, recycling will not grow to substantial
levels; or that collection and disposal are operating at or near capacity
such that tonnage reduction will not "free" an appreciable amount of
equipment. 50
[
[
[
[
r:
L:
[_
[
[
R
Li
[
c
6
The combination of processing and disposal, and landfill savings
from recycling are equal to $11.38 (10.73 + l.lO).for each ton diverted
from solid waste management.
. Summary
I conservatively estimate the potential for secondary material
recovery in Anchorage to be 30,000 tons per year, or about one-fifth of
total coro~ercial and residential Anchorage bowl refuse deposited in
sanitary landfill.
West coast secondary materials demand is strong and growing, and
appears capable of absorbing quantities of accessible waste materials in
Anchorage. Rising secondary materials prices in pacific northwest markets
reflects shortages in competing virgin materials (notably woodpulp) and the
coiT~ercial importance of energy conservation in the production of recycled
COI!L."'!lOdi ties.
Under the existing tariff structure for commodity movement between
Anchorage and Seattle, an individual southbound shipper would contribute
more to backhaul revenues than to costs since most southbound containers
are shipped empty. from the standpoint of the individual shipper, a tariff
reduction that permits commercial operation without lowering backhaul
revenue below carrier cost is reasonable and implies extra revenues to the
carrier that would otherwise not be realized under the existing, commercially-
prohibitive rate structure. However, the backhaul deficit is unlikely
51
[
to increase unless backhaul tariff reductions for secondary materials
are accompanied by increases in southbound commodity movement.
In 1979, 160,084 tons of mixed solid waste was disposed in municipal c
landfill at a total budgeted cost of $9.8 million, or $61 per ton. As
an alternative to disposal, recycling directly affects several elements
of the solid waste management system. Each ton of mixed solid waste
diverted from the waste stream saves $10.73 in processing and disposal
and $1.10 in earnings from delayed expenditures on new landfill site [
development. Until recycling is established on a broader scale, it is
unlikely to initially affect the frequency or spacial distribution of
collection. Nevertheless, collection costs comprise 71 percent of the p
solid waste management budget and offer an opportunity for significant L
savings from recycling. [
r-:
Li
8
B
52
L_J
[
[
c
[
[
r
6
PART III. C~~ENT RECYCLING STATUS
.Anchorage recycling effort may be described as "collection for
external recycling. 11 Viewed as a two stage process, recycling effort
is confined largely to first-stage material recovery in Anchorage. To
date, there' are few examples of instate manufacturing that utilize
materials from the solid waste stream. Consequently, second-stage
reprocessing of solid waste products into raw material substitutes
occurs after secondary materials have been recovered and shipped to
outside users.
Modest internal recycling potential reflects a fundamental character-
istic of Alaska's economy: most commodities are imported. To date,
high cost of capital and wages continue to discourage the development of
local endogenous commodity producing capacity. More importantly, '"i th a
total statewide population of only 400,000 persons, the risk of insufficient
local market demand and the difficulty of achieving adequate economies
of scale continue to hinder industrial development at the expenses of
added dependence on commodity imports. The manufacturing sector in
Anchorage generates two percent of total Anchorage employment and total
payroll, and comprises about 17 percent of statewide manufacturing. The
0
principal segments of this industry are printing and publishing, stone,
glass and clay products, and food and kindred products. It is likely
that until the Anchorage industrial profile, composed largely of services
industries, develops a broader commodity producing sector the potential
for commodity production from secondary materials will similarly remain
dormant.
53
Haterial recovery for external reproce'ssing and reuse is confined
largely to scrap metal with some paper and textile products. Table 3-1
identifies outbound quantities of general secondary materials categories
for selected years. Scrap metal attracts a significant portion of recovery
effort reflecting relatively high demand in west coast and international
secondary materials markets.
Table 3-1 Waste and Scrap Materials Outbound from Anchorage,
~~ittier and Seward Ports in 1973, 1977 and 1978
Material
Iron and Steela
b Non-Ferrous Metal
Paper
Textile
Assumptions:
1973
9,263
5,208
77
aincludes automobile wreckages
b Copper, brass, lead, aluminum
cinc.ludee pipeline clean-up
d Scrap paper and rags
S0urce:
Quantity
(tons)
1977 1978
30,169c 37,969c
552 NA
92d
NA
NA
1. Department of the Army Corps of Engineers, "Waterborne Commerce
of the United States," Part 4, 1976.
2. Alaska Railroad, "Monthly Commodity Statistics."
Scrap Metal Collection
Six organizations are currently involved in scrap metal collection
in Anchorage. With the exception of Stano Steel and Metal Co., Inc.
most collectors are small and deal in specialized scrap metal products.
54
[
n
c
[
[
[
n
[J
j:;
L
[
I~
L
[
[
L
Stano Steel, the largest, independent private scrap metal operation,
collects, separates and decontaminates about half, by weight, of total
Anchorage-based metal recovery shovm in Table 3-2. Hith warehouse and
equipment valued at $1 million and a full time crev-r of eight, Stano Steel
collects a wide range of scrap metal products (including pipeline clean-up)
and in some cases operates strictly as a broker without physically handling
materials.
Table 3-2 identifies an approximate level of scrap metal recovery based
on informal interviews with various collectors. Although total outbound
scrap metal in Table 3-1 is not indicated for 1979, one may infer from
Table 3-2 that the general decline in metal recovery reflects a reduction in
pipeline clean-up. Total metal recovery in Table 3-2 is l±kely to more
accurately refle~t scrap metal generated locally in Anchorage (and the
Jvlatanuska Valley).
All metals are marketed outside of Alaska, including battery and
aluminum exports to Korea, Taiwan, and Japan. In 1979, the total market
value of recovered scrap metal was about $2.2 million, excluding auto-
1 mobile scrap.
In addition to scrap aluminum from aircraft parts, furniture, sidings,
and transformers, about 46 tons of aluminum cans are recovered annually
through a cooperative agreement between the Anchorage Chamber of Commerce
1 Note the price and quantity figures in Table 3-2 are tentative.
They are not composed from accurate records, but instead reflect estimates
specified by individual collectors.
55
Table 3-2 Metal Salvage by Commodity in 1979
Material
Ferrous
Steel
Cast Iron
Automobile
P . a r1ce
($)
$.03/lb·.
.03/lb.
NA
Quantity
(tons per year)
1500
150
3600
TOTAL FERROUS 5250
Non-Ferrous
1-.Thite:
Stainless Steel
Lead (soft)
Battery
Aluminum:
Cans
Other
Zinc
Red:
Copper
Brass
Radiators
.03/lb.
3.00/lb.
.08/lb.
.42/lb.
.45/lb.
.70/lb.
.50/lb.
.46/lb.
40
16
1872
71
372
672
291
93
TOTAL NON-FERROUS 3427
TOTAL FERROUS & NON-FERROUS 8677
$
$
Value
($)
$ 90,000
9,000
NA
99,000
24,000
96,000
312,000
59,640
334,800
940,800
291,000
85,560
2,143,800
2,242,800
aln some cases, prices are approximate because of variation in
the grade of specific metal products.
Source: Stano Steel and Metal Co., Inc.
M & M Enterprises
Boyle Metals Recycling
Jerry the Battery Guy
ABC Auto Supply
Hilltop Sales and Service
56
[
[
{~
[
[
[
b
u
r
1:
b
~ L
L
and Stano Steel. Approximately 60 drop-off dumpsters are dispersed in
specific locations throughout the Anchorage bowl.· Twice a month aluminum
is collected from each dumpster and returned to the Stano Steel warehouse
where it is sorted, shredded and marketed to Japanese and west coast
refineries. Stano Steel provides equipment (dumpsters and dumpster truck),
collection, .and marketing services. The Chamber of commerce establishes
dumpster locations and pick-up schedules. Stano Steel retains 12 cents
per pound of gross receipts to help cover freight and collection experises.
The remaining proceeds from aluminum sales are donated by Stano Steel to
the Chamber of Commerce's aluminum collection program (a non-profit
organization) to cover administration and to finance the Chamber of
Commerce, Anchorage Youth Corps Clean-Up Program. According to one
Chamber of Commerce representative, dumpster contamination from bimetal
cans and other non-aluminum materials increases the costs of sorting and
shredding cans and presents a major deterent to program success.
Between January and September, 197.9, Chamber of Commerce aluminum
can collection averaged about 7,600 pounds (3.8 tons) per month and
totaled 68,481 pounds. On an annual basis, this represents about 6
percent of aluminum can recovery potential identified in Table 2-6.
With the exception of aluminum can collection, which depends on
aluminum donations by the.gen~ral public, scrap metal collectors pay
established rates or bid on available secondary metal. Bids are typically
made for larger lump sum quantities from petroleum and mineral mining,
construction, and railroad operations, but are also contractual for on-
going scrap recovery.
57
[
Waste Oil and Waste Paper Recovery
[
A hand-full of additional, small, specialized enterprises are involved
in recycling assorted non-metal waste products.
c
Alaska Pollution Control (APC) collects and reuses waste oil locally.
With $250,000 in storage tanks, trucks and assorted equipment, APC collects
annually about 200 to 250 thousand gallons of waste oil from service stations, [
maintenance shops, car lots and military bases. Customers pay 12 cents for
each gallon collected by APC. The oil is then stored in settling tanks [
until water settles to the bottom. APC contracts with the municipality or with
private organizations to spray used oil on secondary roads and alleys to
reduce dust and add substance to road surfaces. According to Zalob (1979),
only a small fraction (1 percent) of waste oil used for recovering road
surfaces stays on the road. The remainder, including heavy metal components r'
L.
seeps back into the environment. In general, most waste oil is dumped into
sewers, backyards, and landfill sites without regard to environmental hazards.
About 10 percent of waste oil generated nationwide is re-refined.
From a technical standpoint, Thermo Kool, Inc. is the.only Anchorage
based collection operation that actually recycles secondary materials.
Thermo Kool manufactures cellulose insulation from a combination of news-
print and fire retardant chemicals. Newsprint is conveyed into a hammer
mill where it is shredded and mixed with chemical ingredients. One ton
of cellulose insulation uses three parts newsprint and one part chemical.
Production is tied to statewide construction activity and is therefore
highly cyclical. Thermo Kool consumes about 30 tons per month over a six
month production cycle. This represents about four percent of potential
58
f' c
B
L
c
r
l
f2 ~
I=
L
[
newsprint recovery from Table 2-6. The§ collect and purchase newsprint
from private citizens, from the leftover stock of-newspaper printers,
and from com.rnunity groups engaged in newsprint collection· (e.g. Boy and
Girl Scouts).
As a secondary activity to help generate offseason (January to May)
revenue, Thermo Kool also collects and markets CPO and tab cards to west
coast paper brokers. Although the quantity collected is unknown, Ynermo
Kool purchases non-contaminated CPO and tap cards for not less than $25
per ton.
The newest entry in waste paper collection for recycling is Green
Earth Recycling, a single-person operation that began in January, 1980.
In the first two months of operation Green Earth recovered and marketed
about 16 tons of. CPO and tab cards netting $2,800 in income after deducting
materials purchased and freight expenses from gross receipts of $4,000.
Green Earth pays CPO and tab card users $40 per, ton and is expected to
offer $50 sometime soon. Scott Walyer, president of Green Earth, describes
the strategy of his operation as "low key" recycling. Green Earth contacts
staff level office personnel in state and local government and commercial
inptitutions thAt take it upon themselves to become involved in recycling
in lieu of authorization from top management. The money paid by Green Earth
is typically used to cover office coffee machine expenses. Walyer claims
this technique is effective and is used by other local, independent private
. collectors. However, because of legal and policy considerations concerning
the disbursement of government property (which was previously thrown away)
the Anchorage Municipality is in the process of organizing a bidding system
59
which will properly internalize funds and stimulate paper recovery
simultaneously.
Full Line Recycling: The Alaska Center for
the Environment Recycle Center
In April 1979, the Alaska Center for the Environment (ACE) received
an appropriation from the state legislature to provide start-up funds
for a non-profit, independently operated, full-line recycle center. The
Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center (ACERC) was established
in part to actively participate in material recovery. ACERC also functions
as a demonstration project to explore the difficulties of collecting and
marketing a broad range of secondary materials. The intent of Bob Morrison,
manager of ACERC, is to achieve a breakeven level of material recovery
within the first year of operation.
The ACERC began operations in October, 1979 and performs two basic
functions. First, it operates as a citizen drop-off station for newsprint,
CPO, tab cards, tin and aluminum cans, used motor oil, and worn out car
batteries. Table 3-3 shows monthly frequency of citizen participation
broken do"~ by material type. The frequency of newspaper drop-offs was
highes; followed by aluminum cans and then tin cans. Average participation
grew from a low of 12 deliveries per day in November, to a high of 17
per day in February. Under the interpretation that each delivery represents
a single household, and that the average household is expected to recycle
once a month, the level of participation given in the first 5 months of
operation represents less than 1 percent of Anchorage bowl households.
60
n
c
n tJ
[
n u
[
(;
b
B >
G
Table 3-3
Number of
Month ---Days Opened
November, 1979 25
December, 1979 25
January, 1980 27
Monthly Average
Rec~cling Participation at the Alaska Center for
the Environmental Recycle Center
' .!] L .. J L.
X.!:c~ency of Cit:i.?:cn DroE-Of 1:_ by Material
Newsprint T:ln Oil Aluminum B<1ttcrics
280 32 20 5ll 16
303 37 10 110 9
325 62 9 117 8
303 4LI 13 104 11
Source: Bob Morrison, Manager, ACERC.
'J '· :J
TOTAL ----
301
J]_J
339
318
The second function of the recycle center is ~o collect (i.e. pick up)
CPO and tab cards from organizations that accumulate at least 300 pounds
of combined CPO and tab cards. Table 374 identifies the number of pick-ups
and total weight of collected computer paper from December, 1979 through
February, 1980. About 25 organizations including military (5), state (4),
federal (2), municipal (2), commercial banks (4) and private businesses (8)
provided CPO or tab cards for collection over the indicated 3 months period.
Table 3-4 Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center
Computer Paper Pick-up Frequency
Month Pick-Ups
IBM (tab) Cards CPO Combined
number weight number weight number
(lbs.) (lbs.)
December, 1979 6 1490 13 2920 19
January, 1980 10 2435 17 -6975 27
February, 1980 8 3320 15 5575 23
Source: Bob Morrison, Manager, ACERC
To service deliveries and make pick-ups, the ACERC employs one
full-time manager and two part-time assistants. Whenever possible,
volunteer help from a local pretrail training program for juvenile
offenders is accepted.
62
v.1eight
(lbs.)
4410
9410
8895
[
[
[
c
[
L
n u
[
[
Ll L
The recycle center operates out of a 2,200 square foot quonset
warehouse '~ith 3,000 square feet of additional yard space. In addition
to miscellaneous materials such as pallets, barrels, boxes and binders,
a forklift, a single axle truck with a 12-by 8-by 8.5-foot enclosed
bed, and a baler were purchased with start-up funds. Thus far, the
baler, used normally to compact and compress mixed paper and light
metal, has not been used.
Citizen drop-off is structured to minimize handling. Used news-
. paper is loaded directly into a 40 foot TOTEM trailer which sits in the
recycle center yard. The container is made available to the recycler
for a maximum interval of 10 days. It is then shipped and replaced with
an empty container. Satisfying this time interval is a principal constraint
in newsprint collection for ACERC. If this requirement cannot be met,
then ACERC must pay a penalty fee or stockpile newprint in the warehouse
until sufficient quantity is generated to fill a container. Warehousing
absorbs considerable manpower and storage space which would otherwise be
available for sorting and compacting other materials.
To get around these problems, ACERC sometimes combines shipments
of CPO, tab cards and newsprint into one container. (Recall a single
southbound tariff applies to most grades of paper stock.) Thus, when a
container partially filled with newsprint approaches the end of its on-
location loading interval, CPO and tab cards that have been sorted from
contaminants and bundled on pallets are used to fill available container <
space, and therefore, to reduce the unit transportation cost (cost per
63
ton). However, combined shipments increase the dealers handling costs
and may detract from the market value of total shipment.
Collection of CPO and tab cards absorbs about 2 hours of trucking
for daily pick-ups. Materials are returned, sorted and stockpiled for
eventual bundling. CPO stacks must be sprayed and chemically tested to
check that undesirable carbonless copying chemicals have not evaded sorting
procedures. The value of contaminated CPO declines 80 percent to $50 per
ton and is equivalent to low grade mixed file paper.
For the first five months of operation, ACERC recovered, sorted,
bundled and marketed 184,525 pounds or 92 tons of newsprint, CPO and tab
cards. Gross receipts from secondary material sales were $7,540 ($82/ton).
Shipping costs 2 were $2,689 (5 shipments averaging $538 each) or almost
30 percent of gross receipts.
Table 3-5 presents a quarterly statement of ACERC operating income
and expenses. 'l'he start-up month ot Uctober was not included in order
to more accurately identify on-going expenses. Total variable operating
costs (VOC) have been allocated to individual wastepaper products in
order to isolate and compare cost factors that are pertinent to
specific secondary materials. ACERC purchases newsprint, CPO and
tab cards from users. All material purchases in Table 3-5 apply to
2 The freight cost incurred by ACERC is a special reduced rate granted
by TOTEM. The modified rate is about 87 percent of the original southbound
tariff for waste paper.
64
[
[
[
c
[
[
n
L
[
~
L
._J
n u
[
Table 3-5 · Quarterly Report, Alaska Center for the Environment
(Novenber and December, 1979; January, 1980)
Quantity Sold (tons)
Price per ton
Revenue
36.9
$ 70
$ 2578
Variable Operati~g Cost
(VOC)
Materials
Freight
Laborb
a Purchased 360
1078
989
Truckingc
TOTAL VOC 2427
Gross Operating Profit
(Loss) 151
Fixed Operating Cost
(FOC)
Rent
Advertising
Overheadd
TOTAL FOC
TOTAL VOC and FOC
NET SURPLUS (Deficit)
CPO
10.7
$ 215
$ 2272
% voc %
15
44 314
41 1385
0 198
100 1897
375
TAB
6.4
$ 265
$1671
voc %
0
17 185
73 989
10 116
100 1290
381
$
voc
0
14
77
9
100
Combined
54
6521
360
1577
3363
314
5614
907
2250
296
1947
4493
10,107
(3,586)
~ Assumptions:
a ACERC purchased 18 tons of used newspapers from non-profit
organizations.
b· · Manpower is distributed among newsprint CPO, tab cards, and
overhead as follows:
News
Percent: 25%
Wage bill: $989
CPO
35
1385
Tab
25
989
Overhead
15
595
Total
100%
$3958
Newsprint requires little sorting, but must be neatly stacked in the
container. CPO requires more extensive sorting, stacking, bundling and
to control for other materials that are collected (but not yet marketed)
and general administration.
cTrucking includes operating and maintenance for CPO and tab card collection.
% voc
6
28
60
6
100
(14% Rev:
CPO is allocated 63 percent and tab is allocated 37 percent.
d Overhead includes administration, labor cost, utilities, general maintenance,
supplies, travel and miscellaneous expenses.
65
newsprint only. Of the total quantity shipped, 18 tons or about half
of newspapers delivered were actually purchased by ACERC at $20 per ton
or 1 cent per pound. Freight absorbs 44 percent of newsprint variable
operating costs. The relatively high freight cost on newsprint reflects
larger quantities recovered. The combined cost of freight and materials
purchased absorbs 59 percent of newsprint VOC and 56 percent of newsprint
revenues.
In contrast to newsprint, CPO and tab cards did not incur materials
purchasing costs. The freight factor is also lower. Manpower for CPO
and tab card collection and handling is notably greater than for newsprint,
since newsprint requires only modest restacking in the container. Gross
operating profits (defined as revenue minus variable operating costs) are
positive for all three materials for the specified product mix. Yet the
excess of total revenues over variable operating costs for all materials
combined is not sufficient to cover fixed operating costs,-which alone,
equal 69 percent of total revenues. (We also· ignore equipment costs equal
Lu $12,700 rnvPrPd hy the slat~ grant.)
In order to break even (i.e. to attain a level of recovery such that
annw'll tntAl rPVenues equal annual total costs, collection and marketing
must expand to a quarterly total of 267 tons (1068 annual tonnage),
using the same product mix proportions specified in Table 3-5. By
focusing recovery efforts on tab cards and CPO, which exhibit higher
unit, gross profitability than newspapers, the break even level of total
66
[
L
L
[
[
[J
L
c B
r
recovery is reduced somewhat depending on the specific product mix.
Kevertheless, an approximate fivefold increase in marketable tonnage is
required to cover all expenses. All else equal, participation by residents
and commercial organizations must jump from .6 to 3 percent in order to
generate break even tonnage.
The above break even analysis is based only on private costs and
benefits recognized in the market and internalized by market prices.
Recall that a number of hidden costs and benefits are not captured in
the market for secondary materials. These include savings of extended
landfill life, reduced processing and disposal costs, and from a broader
standpoint, reduced pollution and environmental damage.
From t·hese benefits, however, we "net out" the non-market cost of
time and effort to separate secondary materials from household waste and
deliver it to the recycle center. Recycling-operates in a social
framework that routinely and permanently discards used materials as
valueless waste. In order to integrate recycling into this "throw-away"
structure, citizens must spend extra time and energy to so.rt and deliver
recyclables to ACERC. To approximate these costs >..re estimate the amount
of time required to source-separate the specified quantity. We assume
that the opportunity cost of manpower in source separation is equal to
the average second quarter, 1979 wage rate in Anchorage ($7.09) times
the total amount of time allocated to -v1aste separation.
L
L
67
Over the 3 month period, a total of 953 households (318 per month)
delivered about 25 pounds of recyclables per trip. Each participating
household is assumed to spend 14.2 minutes per month (PRT, 1975, p.24)
sorting newsprint. On average, each delivery is assumed to cover a
roundtrip distance of 7 miles. SO percent of citizen deliveries are
assumed to occur in conjunction with other errands and are ignored. In
Table 3-6, the total "external" cost of source separating and delivering
54 tons of assorted waste paper is $2,417.
The effect of recycling 54 tons of waste paper on landfill site
longevity saves $60 in delayed replacement expenditures. Processing and
disposal savings amount to $579 or 91 percent of total external benefits.
Although not an explicit component of external benefits,3 energy conservation
corresponding to forgone paper production from raw materials is equal to
280 million Btus and converts to 50 barrels of crude petroleum equivalence.
External benefits in Table 3-6 are likely to be understated, since the
benefits of reduced environmental damage are riot quantified.
Under the assumptions given in this particular example, external
costs exceed benefits by $1~778 or $34 per ton collected. However, it may
be argued that the cost of household source sepArAtion AS rAlrnlAtPcl in
3 I assume that the value of energy savings is captured in rising
market prices.
68
[
[
[
[
[
[
E
__;
r:
Table 3-6 External Benefits and Costs
Estimates for 54 Tons of Paper Recovery
External Costs
Source Separation
953 households at 14.2 minutes
each, 'at an implicit wage of $7.09
per hour.
$ 1,599
Delivery-818
50 percent of deliveries occur in
conjunction with other errands and are
ignored. Thus, 477 deliveries at 7 miles
each, 10 m.p.g. times $1.25/gallon ($418)
plus 12 cents per mile for maintenance ($400).
TOTAL EXTE&~AL COSTS
External Benefits
Processing and Disposal
$10.73/ton diverted
Landfill Longevity
$1.10/ton
Total External Savings
Net Benefits (Costs)
Energy Conservation eJ
5.6 x 106 Btu/ton are sav~ by
recycling and foregoing paper
production from faw material.
280 million Btu is equal to
50 barrels of crude petroleum
using 5.6 million Btu/barrel.
Assume $24 per barrel.
69
$ 2,417
$ 579
60
$ 639
($ 1, 778)
1,200
Table 3-6 overstates the actual burden implied by recycling. Home
separation of recyclables easily integrates into routine household
chores without disturbing normal patterns of lifestyle (Hayes, 1978).
The implicit wage used in Table 3-6 more realistically represents
an upper limit that corresponds to the cost of hiring private labor to
substitute for ongoing resident participation in household source
separation.
Thus, the social cost of household source separation is, at best,
tentative. If we ignore the cost of household source separation as
calculated in Table 3-6 net non-market costs reduce to $179. To the
extent that savings in energy and in environmental integrity are not
captured in market pr~ces, net costs are further reduced.
In eumma.ry, vJe twl!.! Llkl.L 9, 000 Luu:s uf scrap mf>rAl Al"P rt-coVC'ted
annually by six Anchorage-based scrap metal collectors. Two thirds of
this is generated locally in Anchorage and represents about 41 percent
of total ferrous and non-ferrous metal waste entering mixed and solid
0
waste. A single waste oil collector recovers and reuses 250,000
gallons annually. At least three organizations are involved in limited
paper recovery and together are responsible for total monthly recovery
of over 56 tons assorted paper. This represents less than 5 percent of
waste paper that is available for recovery.
70
[
[
[
[
f' LJ
F. l
[
F
6
E
h
L
r·
i.Jith the exception of Chamber of Commerce aluminum can collection
and the Alaska Center for. the Environment's full-time recycle center,
all collection operations are profit-motivated. Generally, collection
is specialized and small scale. Payment is usually made to users that
deliver or make available waste·materials to collectors. Exceptions are
the Chamber of Commerce vlhich depends on citizen donations of aluminum
cans, and Alaska Pollution Control which charges users to collect their
"'aste oil. The Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center purchases
assorted waste paper strictly from non-profit organizations.
THo observations are relevant at this point. First, the potential
secondary material for recovery is largely untapped in Anchorage, although
an active, somewhat low key, assembly of collectors exist. The recycling
rate in Anchorage is substantially less than the national average of
25 to 30 percent for general materials. This reflects a more fundamental
problem: resident participation in recycling _is, for all intents and purposes,
negligible.
To a large extent, negligible participation reflects a general lack
of awareness about recycling and its potential impact. Additionally, there
are few, if any, economic incentives currently operating that stimulate
consumer involvement. This, in part, reflects the problem of hidden
benefits not captured in market exchange. In Part V, we explore policy
proposals aimed at exp~sing benefits and stimulating citizen participation.
Before doing so, we explore the affects of expanding resident and commercial
participation in Part IV.
71
72
[
r
~
c
c
[
[
~
. c
[
[;
L
k
L
r
L
I
[J
~
R
L
L
PART IV. RECYCLING SCENARIOS
In this section, we examine three alternate recycling scenarios.
Each scenario may be thought o~ as an experiment. The basic recycling
scenario d·epicts a nonprofit, full-line recycling center that depends
on secondary material donations by household residents and commercial
institutions. The basic scenario also establishes a frame of reference
to evaluate the effects of changing the commercial status and collec-
tion policy.
The buy-back scenario simulates recycling under the assumption
that the recycle center is profit-oriented and offers to pay customers
for specific secondary materials. The basic and buy-back scenarios are
distinguished mainly by the profile of materials they recover (i.e.,
product mix) reflecting more fundamental differences in commercial
status.
The office-collection scenario modifies the buy-back scenario
·conditions by introducing a comprehensive program in which state
offices separate high-grade office ledger paper from other materials
and sell it to the recycle center.
We assume for all scenarios a constant level of resident and
commercial participation in recycling. Specifically, 25 percent of
households separate tin, aluminum, glass, and wastepaper. Commercial
institutions contribute approximately 25 percent of recoverable
73
computer printouts (CPO), tab cards, and corrugated containers (CC)
estimated in Part II.
Household and institution~l participation, therefore, functions
as a control variable in the recycling experiments and creates an
opportunity to examine more closely the effects of operational and
structural changes. However, by holding the level of participation
constant, we do not mean to imply that it is less important to the
analysis. Citizen participation in recycling is difficult to predict
1 or model and from a scientific point of view is best left unchanged.
The assumption of 25 percent participation reflects average par-
ticipation in the United States as a whole. For example, a recent
Seattle program in collection of household recyclables experienced
overall participaLion of 23 percent (SRI, 1979). Lee Barrett, General
Manager of the Portland Recycling Team, conservatively estimates recycl-
ing pArtidpAtion there at 35 percent.
The analysis of each scenario considers two levels of benefit
and cost as criteria for an evaluation of economic feasibility. In
the first level, designated "commercial feasibility," only private
sector revenue and cost factors are used; other non-market value con-
siderations are ignored. If commercial feasibility is satisfied,
1Note that the total quantity of material recovery changes
between scenarios, reflecting changes in product mix, but not in
participation.
74
[
c
[
n L
H
L
L
private benefits exceed costs and the scenario w~uld be profitable
"\.Jithout government financial assistance.
_ _j
__j The second level of benefits and costs is designated "social
feasibility." Here, non-market costs and benefits similar to those
_j
identified in the earlier example concerning ACERC are incorporated
to adjust private factors and create a more comprehensive benefit/
cost profile. If social feasibility is satisfied, then the combina-
tion of private and public benefits (i.e., social benefits) exceed
social costs. Satisfaction of social, but not commercial, feasibility
is a necessary condition for government financial assistance. How-
ever, if social benefits do not cover social costs, the criteria for
social feasibility is not satisfied and government subsidies would not
~e economically justified.
Basic Scenario
The basic recycle center scenario is a nonprofit, full-line
·operation with a primary goal of handling the maximum quantity of
materials generated by community participation. It does not incor-
porate a policy of buying recovered secondary materials from con-
~ .·
sumers but depends instead on resident and institutional donations.
The recycle .center in the basic scenario is similar in design to that
of the Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center (ACERC),
except that ACERC purchases a limited range of materials from non-
profit organizations.
L
75
Recovery and Revenue
The quantity and composition of recyclable household material
sho"~ in Table 4-1 were taken from estimates by the Council on
Environmental Quality and modified to reflect current trends in
2 Anchorage.
Table 4-1. The Quantity and Composition of Residential
1-Jaste Per Household (HH) for Selected Haterials
Haterial
Newspaper
Other Paper
Glass
Ferrous (tin cans)
Aluminum (cans)
Lbs. /HH/Honth
22
16.42
24.17
4
1
Source: Council on Environmental Quality
Lbs. /HH/Yr.
265
197
290
48
12
In this analysis, the total number of households are limited to
residential districts in the Anchorage bowl, Eagle River, and Chugiak.
Turnagain Arm and milit:wy populations are excluded. The Hunicipal
Planning Office estimate for 1979 housing units in the Anchorage bowl
is 57,463, of which 9.1 percent are vacant. Approximately 4,500 addi-
tional homes are located in Eagle River and Chugiak. At 25 percent, the
participating portion of total-occupied housing for the specified area
is about 14,000.
2 Generally, higher aluminum and paper consumption and lower glass
consumption than national average.
76
[
c
[
n L
[
I] Ll
[
Participation in the coauercial sector is also assumed to be 25
percent of pote.ntic.l recovery. The conn:nercial sec tor includes federal,
state., and municipal offices; private companie.s; and public institu-
tions. Waste materials gener~ted in this sector are computer printouts
(CPO), IBM tablulating cards (tab cards), and corrugated containers
(CC).
}ionthly and annual quantity estimates are given in Table 4-2 for
14,000 participating households, based on the information in Table 4-1.
Note that if each household delivers recyclables once a month, then the
monthly quantity delivered per household is about 68 pounds. n
L
[ Revenue potential for the specified product mix is presented in
Table 4-3. Comparing the mass of a given material to its market value
provides a partial indicator of the material's relative value. Under
current market conditions, mixed scrap, CC, and glass containers are
worth lese per unit of recovered mace than all other mnterialo
listed. On the other end of the spectrum, the market value of aluminum
relative to its mass is exceptionally high.
Total revenue from the recyled materials in the basic scenario
would be equal to $436,423 in 1980 dollars, of which waste paper
materials would contribute 65 percent. Overall revenue potential is
approximately $70 per ton.
77
Table 4-2. Total Residential and Commercial Quantity
and Composition of Recyclable Materials
(tons)
Residential (86% of total quantity)
Material Total Amount Percent Residential
per month per year
Newsprint 155 1855 33
Other Paper 115 1379
Krafta 10% 11.5 138
24
Scrap 90% 103 1241
Glass 169 2030 36
Ferrous 28 336 6
Aluminum 7b 84 l
TOTAL RESIDENTIAL 474 5684 100
Cowuercial (14% of total quantity)
Material Total &'11ount Percent Commercial
per month per vear
CPOc 20 238 25
Tab cardsc 5.4 65 7
cc 53 637 68
TOTAL COMMERCIAL 78.4 940 100
GRAND TOTAL 552 6624
Assumptions:
a Brown paper bags.
b Assumes 4 lbs. per household per month. Based on rfetropolitan
Service District, City of Portland estimate.
cincludes military quantites.
78
[
[
[
c
L
n L
[
[.
-.·1 -cj
;J
L
~-j
---' .
n
L;
[
r -
r:
Table 4-3. Basic Scenario Revenue Potential
Annual Percent of Annual Percent of
Haterial Amount Total \,reight Price/ton Revenue Total Revenue
(tons) ($) ($)
Paper
Newsprint 1855 28 70 148,400 32
Kraft a 138 2 150 20,700 4
Hixed Scrap 1241 19 20 24,820 5
CPO 238 3 215 51,170 11
Tab cards 65 1 265 17,225 4
cc 637b 10 55-75 38,220 8
Glass (mixed) 2030 31 30C 60,900 13
Ferrous 336 5 78 26,208 5
(tin cans)
Aluminum cans 84 1 900 75,600 16
TOTAL 6624 100 463,423 100
a Brown paper bags.
b .
75 percent of total OCC is prebaled in non-commercial sizes
(3-1/2-4'), receiving $55 per ton; 25 percent is baled in the recycle
center receiving $75 per ton.
c Northwest Glass Co., Seattle, Hashington.
].~e~overy TechnoJ.:ogy
The cost of recovering waste materials may be divided into three
general classifications: collection, processing, and freight. A
broad range of collection and processing techniques exist. Appli-
cability or suitablllLy ui a gl.vt::u technique depends on a hoot of ·con-
ditions, including:
l.
2.
3.
The commercial status (profit or nonprofit) and pay-back
policy.
The product mix and the '"eight, mass, degree of homogeneity,
and level of contamination of each material.
The physical characteristics of a community, its density
and dispersion, and its proximity to secondary materials
markets.
79
Operating costs are categorized as fixed or· variable depending
on whether or not a given cost element is affected by the quantity of
recovery.
Colleetion. Waste materials would be collected at two levels in
order to control for moderate dispersion which characterizes the location
of residential and commercial sub-districts in the Anchorage bowl for
newsprint and glass. Drop-boxes with an avarage 30-cubic-yards capacity
would be located throughout the Anchorage bowl to maximize user conve-
nience and area-wide material recovery. These boxes would be segmented
to allow separating newsprint and glass, as well as different colors
of glass. We assume that 75 percent of total glass and newsprint would
be recovered via the drop-boxes. The remaining 25 percent plus other
residential waste materials, including mixed scrap paper, -kraft (brown
paper bags), and tin and aluminum cans, would be delivered directly to
the recycle center drop-off station. Drop-boxes are permissable because
the basic scenario does not incorporate a buy-back policy. The drop-box
collection would be restricted to newsprint and glass to prevent exten-
·sive contamination of recyclables from carelessly deposit~d materials.3
A single "roll-off" container truck would be used to service drop-
boxes. Assuming an average density of 500 pounds per cubic yard for
3 This was the experience of the Stano Steel/Chamber of Commerce
aluminum collection program which distributes drop-boxes or dumpster
bins for aluminum only.
80
[
[
[
B
n [;
6 ' .
t:
c
[
materials delivered in drop-boxes (Quimby, 1975), four drop-boxes
would be picked up and replaced daily.
The annual trucking cost of servicing a residential drop-box
4 collectiGn route covering 17,280 miles is estimated at $8,160.
The second level of collection pertains to commercially generated
CPO, tab cards, and CC. A minimum of 300 pounds of combined paper
products would have to be accumulated prior to pick up. At 300 pounds
per pickup, the monthly quantity of commercially-generated waste
paper would equal about 25 pick-ups per day.
Two single-axle, 12-14 foot-long enclosed trucks, operating con-
tinuously, would be required to satisfy the frequency of commercial
·collection. The annual total non-payroll commercial trucking expense
. 5
is estimated at $9,225.
Processing. In general, processing waste materials refers to
sorting, decontaminating, and compacting. The more carefully these·
4we assume tbe average round-trip distance from drop-box to·recycle
center would equal 15 miles. Fuel cost is estimated at $1.25 per gallon,
assuming an average 10 mpg fuel economy. Maintenance ($2,000) and in-
surance ($4,000) are added to fuel cost to derive total residential
drop-box collection costs.
5 Based on actual ACERC experience, each pick-up averages seven
miles round trip. Total annual mileage equals 63,000 miles. Fuel
economy is 10 mpg at $1.25 per gallon. Annual maintenance and insurance
are estimated at $450 and $900, respectively.
81
tasks are achieved, the greater the market value of recyclables. For
example, shredded aluminum usually receives a higher price than crushed
aluminum, which requires comparatively more handling and reprocessing
by the ultimate user. Mixed cullet (broken glass) not separated by
color is r€jected by glass manufacturers.
Processing, manpower, and equipment requirements depend on specific
characteristics of the materials recovered. Table 4-4 outlines specific
processing requirements for the basic scenario recovery configuration.
Except for newsprint, all wastepaper products require some sorting and
compacting (either by baling or bundling). CC must first undergo pre-
crushing before it is baled, in order to achieve cost-effective density.
(Even then, CC density is only about 25 percent that of newsprint.)
In general, processing glass containers requires more elaborate
handling and equipment. In the basic scenario, bottles from drop-box
collections would have to be checked for proper color separation and
metal components removed. Bottles of a certain color would be fed
·into a crusher and then conveyed into 25-foot, open-top, hydraulic lift
containers 6 (similar in design to a gravel trailer) for shipment.
6 This hydraulic lift feature is the only practical design for
unloading cullet at the glass manufacturing plant. Cullet is unmanage-
able and difficult to remove vertically or horizontally. It must,
therefore, be dumped. The open-top container is non-standard and is
not available from carriers. Northwest Glass Company in Seattle is
unwilling to provide container equipment. In the basic scenario, I
assume that the recycle center invests in four such containers to handle
the quantity of recovered cullet. Note that it may be possible to· leave
the container to another shipper for its northbound return trip to Seattle.
82
[
·" ... [._j
[
[
rn
Material
~
Kraft
Mixed Scrap
occ
CPO
Tab cards
CtJ w Newsprint
Glass
Aluminum
Tin
mti .. J .J ·t
. Table 4-4. Basic Scenario Processing Requirements
Daily Quantity
(lbs.)
958 lbs/day
8583
1104
} 2117
12917
14083
2333
583
Processing Techni~
}
sort, bale,
stockpile,
precrush OCC prior
to baling
)
sort, test,
bundle on pallet
no processing,
load container
remove metal parts,
color separate, crush
stockpile in drums or bins
}
remove bimetal,
flatten, blow
stockpile
l... J .J
Processing Crew
. (all full-time)
}1 baler, 2 sorters
) 1 sorter~bundler
1 sorter
1 sorter, 1 crusher
} 1 sorter-equipment operator
Aluminum-and tin-can processing is similar to that of glass.
Aluminum and tin cans are hand-collected separately. Each type is
checked for bimetal components and then fed into a hopper where they
are crushed and blown into a storage bin. Processed secondary materials
are either stockpiled or loaded directly into standby containers (supplied
by the carrier).
In addition to that required for collecting and processing, equip-
ment is needed for general operations. This includes a forklift, scales,
tables, tools, supplies, and office furniture. An equipment cost break-
down is specified in Table 4-5. Total equipment cost is equal to
$182,107. This converts to $54,630 in annual capital recovery cost for
debt amortized over 5 years at 15-percent interest.
Recycle center employment for the basic scenario is divided into
administrative, collecting, and processing categories in Table 4-6. The
structure of adminictrativc pcroonncl rcflcct:J !Jtaff organization at
Portland Recycle Team (PRT). Pay-scale ranking is also derived from
PRT with adjustments suited to the higher cost of living in Alaska.
(Salaries include 15 percent for fringe benefits.) The production crew
in processing is derived from the workload specified in Table 4-4.
Annual total wages and salaries would be $189,500.
Freight. Transporting costs are an important element in the over-
all cost of Anchorage-based recycling. Backhaul tariffs differ by
commodity. All paper categories receive the same tariff. In general,
84
[
[
[
c
D
[
(::
L
F t
~-1
n
L
r '-.
r u
g
LJ
[
Table 4-5. Basic Recycling Scenario --Equipment Costsa
for Collection, Processing, and General Operation
Collection
Trucks (1) Roll-off container
(2) Single axle, f4', enclosed
Drop boxes (23) @ $2,200 each, plus freight
Trailer (4) Open top, hydraulic lift
(25 x 8 x 8 @ $9,000 each)
Processing
Baler -vertical stroke
Glass Crusher -conveyor
Metal Flatlever -blower
General Operation
Forklift
Scales
Tables
Storage bins -12 @ $600 each, ·plus f_reight
Barrels -24 @ $25 each
Miscellaneous equipment
TOTAL EQUIPHENT
alncludes freight from Seattle
40,000b
9,000c
53,415d
36,000
5,324
8,292d
5,108c
e 5,498d
3,146
500
7, 718b
600
7,500
b Lee Barrettt, General Hanager, Portland Recycle Team,
Portland, Oregon
c Used
d Don Knease, General Hanager, Seattle Recycling, Inc.,
Seattle, Washington
eBob Harrison, Hanager, Alaska Center for the Environment
Recycle Center
85
$138,415
18,724
24,962
$182,101
Table 4-6. Basic Recycling·Scenario
Personnel and Payroll
Administration
General Manager
Bookkeeper
Marketing Manager
Public Relations Manager
Collection
Drivers (3) @ $20,700 each
Processing
Warehouse Manager
Production Crew ($5/hr.)
Baler (1)
Sorter (4)
Bundler (1)
Crusher (2)
25,875
16,675
20,125
17,250
62,100
15,000
9,600
38,400
9,600
19,200
TOTAL EMPLOYMENT
86
$ 79,925
62,100
91,800
$233,825
[
[
[
c
(=,J
L
L
larger shipments receive lower rates per unit weight. Table 4-7 cal-
culates the annual total freight charge for each material in the
basic scenario. Densities are based on the form in which the materials
are shipped: baled, bundled, c~ushed, flat, or loose-stacking specific
materials.· I assume that a 40-by 8-by 8.5-foot container of 100 cubic
yards capacity would be used for all materials except glass. The ICC
has established a maximum limit of 42,000 pounds (21 tons) for a
40-foot container. Materials not having sufficient density will fill the
volume capacity of a container before reaching ICC weight limitations.
(This is the case for CC, tin, and aluminum.) The annual transportation
cost of exporting 6,624 tons of recyclables is equal to $158,778, or $24
per ton.
Commercial Feasibility
Cost and revenue relationships identified in Tables 4-3 through
4-7 are brought together by Table 4-8 in a comprehensive statement of
ostim::Jtad privata s40ic.tor revennoa~:: and ii<XpQnsOis. Alloc:<tion of costs
for collecting, processing, and shipping material are based on quantity,
volume, and manpower requirements identified above; Table 4-8 com-
pares the effects on costs of collecting, processing, and shipping
on each material a~d provides for convenient manipulation in subsequent
scenario adjustments.
Costs of collecting, processing, and shipping are components of
annual cost which, by definition, vary directly with the volume of
secondary material recovered. Fixed costs not directly affected by
l; 87
OJ
OJ
Table 4-7. ·Basic Scenario Freight Specifications and Costs
Monthly Quantity Compacted Quantity per Number of Tariff a per
Material Recovered Density 40' Container Containers Per Container
(tons) (lbs/ft) (tons) month year ($)
Newsprint 155 20 7 84
Mix Scrap 103 21 5 60
Kraft 11.5 21 21 .5 6 $566
CPO 20 25 1 12
Tab Cards 5.4 30 .25 3
cc 53 8 10.5 5 60 359
Glass 169 28 21 8 96 336
Tin 28 9 12.5 2.25 27 336
Aluminum 7 5.5 7 1 12 210
TOTAL 552 360
aThe tariff per container is based on published (Sea Land) tariffs associated with a full
contai:ner load (whether or not this load is met) or on published tariffs for the actual weight
of the shipment, independent of container ·size,·whichever is less. See above discussion of
transportation structure in part II.
~. .J
Total Annual
Freight
($)
$ 47,544
33,960
3,396
6 '792
1,698
21,540
32,256
9,072
2,5QO
$158 '778
• ·~
CY.l
\0
[~ L .: .. J l. I l. L.:: ... H
Table 4-8. Basic Scenario Distribution of
Revenues and Costs by Material
Resi~ential Recovery
Hixed
Newsprint Kroft Scrnp Glass
Quant:l.ty Received (tons) 1,855 138 1, 241 2,030
Revenue 148,400 20,700 24,820 a0,900
Vorinble Operutins Cost (voq
a 18,990 :..8,990 Co11ectionh
Process!ng 11,550 5,700 17,250 ::2,950
Freight 47,5411 3,396 33,960 32,256
Total voc 78,084 9,096 51,210 ;tl,l96
Gross Operating Profit (Loss) 70,316 11,604 (26,390) (13,296)
aCo11ection costs are distributed ~n proportion to vo1mme.
h Processing costs include warehouse manager and production
crew poyroll distributed according to material specific
labor requirements in Table 23,
cSee Tnhle 4~7 for details.
dWatehouse floor space is equal to 7,500 square ft.
Rental is equal to 40 cents per square foot.
cOverhcad includes utilities, office supplies, phone, ...-orehouse
supplies, maintenance and depreciation. Overhead i~ not
necessarily fixed, and instead varies with the level of act:l.vity,
although not directly with production. Overhead is estJmated
as 18 percent of total VOC.
fSce 'L'uble. /1-S for details.
rl!!.
336
26,208
5,700
_1,072
14 '772
11,1136
Product H:ilc
Alum:lnum
811
75,600
5 '700
Ll20
8,220
67,380
Commcrclnl RecoverL__ __
Totul
ReB Jd en t 111 J CPO TAll cc -----
5' 6811 238 65 637
356,628 51,170 17,225 38,220
37,980 12,150 2,531 35,9114
68,850 5,700 5,700 11,550
128,]1·8 __ 6,792 .l,698 3.!,540
235,578 24 '642 9,929 69,034
121,050 26,528 7,296 (30,814)
Fixed Operating Cost (FOC)
. d
Warehouse (rental)
Gcnernl Administration Payroll
Ove1:head 0
Total FOG
Total Oper;lting Costs (VOC + FOG)
OpcrntJng Surplus (Deficit)
f Capital Recovery Cost (CRC)
Total
Cnmmc t•c ia1
9/10
106,615
50,625
22,950
30 1 030
100,365
3,010
ANNUAL TOTAl, COSTS (VOC + FOG + CRC)
J\NNlJJ\1, Nln INCmm (LOSS)
~J.
Totnl ReoJdcntial
nnd Conunr"·c:lnl
6,67./1
/163,211]
88,605
91,800
.!.?.!L_UB
339,183
12/1,060
36,000
79,925
_i.!_,Q1_~
176' 977
516,160
(52,917)
sr1 ,630
570,790
(107 ,Sial)
Per Ton
69.93
51.21
the quantity of material recovered include staff payroll, general
overhead, warehouse rental, and capital recovery costs.
We assume for the basic scenario that gross operating profits
(i.e. revenues minus variable operating costs) would be negative for
mixed scrap, glass, and CC. All remaining secondary materials generate
gross profits high enough to compensate for unprofitable material re-
covery. However, although there would be a gross operating profit
for the entire product mix, it would not be enough to cover all fixed
operating and capital costs. Consequently, annual net losses in the
basic scenario would exceed $108,000. Net losses would equal $7.68
per year for each participating household and reduce to $1.91 per
household for total households in the Anchorage bowl.
The results in Table 4-8 indicate that expanding the range and
quantity of material recovery to a level tw.enty-five times greater
net profit or even enough revenues to cover costs. The aggregate
level of secondary material recovery would have to expand by 80 per-·
cent to 12,372 tons in order for total revenues to match total costs.7
If we ignore capital recovery costs, then the breakdown level of ·
7 rt is likely that increases this large would require additional
equipment and personnel and, thus, raise annual operating plus capital
·recovery costs beyond the level indicated in Table 4-8. Thus, the
above breakeven calculations may understate the breakeven level of
material recovery.
90
[
[
[
[
n
L
[
f'
[~
[
8
G
~ L
I :
L
recovery would have to rise 43 percent over the level of original
recovery to 9,454 tons.
-
Basic scenario recovery tor recycling is designed to simulate the
operation of a nonprofit, full-line recycle center under the principle
of maximum secondary material recovery. Mixed scrap, glass, and CC all
contribute unfavorably to the financial profile she~~ in Table 4-8. In
order to identify hm,r mixed scrap, glass, and CC affect ·commercial
feasibility, we exclude these materials from the basic scenario product
six.
r
L. A number of important equipment, personnel, and organizational
[ changes are implemented to accommodate the modified product mix. Most
importantly, the system of city-wide, drop-box delivery depots are
eliminated in favor of a single, centrally located recycling drop-off
station where all payments for recyclables are issued.
B
Consequently, roll-off container truck and the drop boxes are
eliminated. Plant capacity would be reduced from 7,500 to 5,000 square
feet, reflecting most notably the spacial requirements for glass and
CC. Elaboration of yard facilities to accommodate heavier traffic would
be required.
In addition, the glass crush-conveyor for open-top glass con-
t:=
L tainers, four storage bins, and twenty-four barrels--all related to
t:
glass--are no longer required. Because CC is no longer collected,
L
91
one single-axle commercial collection vehicle is dropped. The total
value of foregone equipment is $146,666, about 80 percent of the
original cost of capital. Total remai~ing equipment is equal to
$35,435, which reduces to $10,630 in annual capital recovery costs.
Personnel adjustments exclude four production crew and two drivers
from the basic scenario employment configuration. Freight is reduced
substantially from the basic scenario, corresponding to the elimination
of 216 annual container loads of mixed scrap, glass, and CC.
Omitting CC reduces commercial collection to 25 tons of CPO and
tab cards per month, or about eight pick-ups per day. Annual trucking
expenses, excluding driver, now equal $2,916, for fuel, maintenance,
and insurance.
The effect of eliminating these materials-from the basic scenario
is shown in Table 4-9. Unit variable operating costs corresponding
to the modified product mix increase slightly to $53.29, suggesting the
onset of diseconomies from the 59 percent decline in aggregate material
r~covery from 6,624 to 2,716 tons. Nevertheless, by eliminating the
secondary materials that have low earning potential, unit revenues
increase dramatically. Thus, the commercial losses of $16.24 per ton
in the basic scenario are replaced by a commercial gain equal to $39,000,
or $14.40 per ton. Thus, commercial feasibility is satisfied in the
modified basic scenario.
92
n
f' u
r-'
b
: g
~.
L
L
-
F
0
I=
L
Table 4-9. SuL'21c.ry Statement of Revenues c.:1d Expenses for Basic Scenario
c.nd Basic -Scenario with Modified Product Mix
l\_~£Y.C}:_ing S c en?_Ij __ o ____ _
Basic with Dollars per Ton
Hod if ied in the Hod if ied
Basic Product Hix Product Mix
Quantity Recovered 6,624 tons 2,716 tons
-Revenue $463,243 $339,303 124.93
Variable Operating Costs (VOC)
Collection 88,605 33,671
Processing 91,800 40,050
Freight 158' 778 71,022
Total VOC $339,183 $144,743 53.29
Gross Operating Profit $124,060 $194,560
Fixed Operating Costs (FOC)
\·7arehouse 36,000 24,000
Administrative Payroll 79,925 79,925
Overhead 61,052 40,905a
Total FOC $176,977 $144,830
Total Operating Costs $516,160 $289,573
(VOC + FOC)
Operating Surplus (Deficit) (52,917) (49' 730)
Capital Recovery Cost (CRC) 54,630 10,630
Annual Total Costs 570,790 300,203
l\et Income (Loss) Before Tax $(107,547) $ 39,100 14.40
a 67 percent of basic scenario overhead, based on decline in
plant size.
93
The results of product mix adjustments in tbe basic scenario
suggest that the commercial feasibility of a recycling recovery system
depends as much on the level of aggregate material recovery as it does
on the type of materials recovered. By· eliminating specific unprofitable
materials,-the basic scenario could become commercially feasible. How-
ever, aggregate material recovery would decline by 60 percent or 3,900
tons of used glass and paper. A closer look at specific public (non-
market) benefits and costs illustrates the desirability of adjusting
the basic scenario product mix from the standpoint of social feasibility.
Social Feasibilitv
In order to evaluate social feasibility in the basic scenario, we
measure external, non-market benefits and costs of material recovery and
integrate the result with the gains or losses realized under co~mercial
conditions. Non-market social costs, as defined here, include the
opportunity cost of time and effort ih home_preparation (source separa-
tjnn) nf rPcyrlRhl P<;J pln"! ;:m pc;timRtP nf fnPl rnnsmnpti nn rnsts for
resident delivery to the recycle center. Source-separation of news-
print, glass, tin, and aluminum cans would require a total of 72.7
minutes of monthly home preparation (PRT, 1975, p. 24). The breakdown
for each material is presented in Table 4-10.
94
[
[
r·
e
LJ
B
!:= L·
I :
L
=
Tcble 4-10. Home Separation Requ1rements
Haterial
Newspaper
Glass
Tin cans
Aluminum
Source: ?RT, 1975.
Preparation
Time Per Honth
14.2
19.8
33.1
5.6
72.7
"External benefits," as used here, include cost reductions in the
municipal waste management system as a result of reduced tonnage of
mixed solid waste. These reductions include savings in processing and
disposal and in delayed expenditures on new landfill site development.
Not included are potential savings in the cost of refuse collection
that would be realized by either individual residents or the municipality.
we assume thct energy savings associated with reduced raw material proc-
essing would be reflected in rising secondary materials prices and
are not included in the estimate of external benefits.
Table 4-11 summarizes the effects of external benefits and costs
on social feasibility for the basic scenario and its modified counter-
part. External costs would be substantially larger than external
benefits in both scenarios. Consequently, neither scenario would
satisfy the conditions for social feasibility; in both cases, combined
private and public costs would exceed benefits. Note, however, that
net social costs per ton would be lower for the unadjusted basic see-
nario. This suggests that from the standpoint of social feasibility
95
Table 4-11. Social Feasibility of Basic Scenario and
Basic with Modified Product Mix
External Costs
Residential Fuel Consumption
Source Separation
Total External Costs
External Benefits
Processing and Disposal
Landfill Longevity
Total External Benefits
Net External Benefits (Costs)
Net Commercial Income (Loss)
Net Social Benefits (Costs)
Net Social Benefits (Cost)
Per Ton
Basic
6,624 Tons
$ 42,078a c 1,443,240
$1,485,388
$ 71,076
7,286
$ 78,362
$(1,407,026)
$ (107,547)
$(1,514,743)
$ (229)
Basic, excluding glass,
Mixed Scrap and CC
$
2, 716 Tons
b 31,500d
1,052,156
$1,083,656
$ 29,143
2,988
$ 32,131
$(1,051,525)
$ 39,100
$(1,012,425)
$ (373)
a SO percent of total recycle center residential delivery plus all
drop box deposits are excluded from fuel consumption calculation as
conjunctive errands. Effective annual quantity delivered is equal to
1,611 tons. As before, assume participating households recycle 67 pounds
of assorted paper, glass, and metal per month and 7 miles round trip.
Total mileage is 336,627 based on 48,089 trips. Fuel economy is lO"miles
per gallon. Fuel cost equals $1.25 per gallon.
bThe effective annual quantity delivered by residents is 1,206 tons
and implies 36,00,0 deliveries at 67 pounds per delivery, per mon~h.
Total mileage is 252,000, assuming an average of 7 round trip miles per
delivery. Fuel economy is 10 miles per gallon.
c A total of 72.7 minutes is required for monthly home preparation
of newsprint, glass, tin cans, and aluminum (PRT, 1975, p. 24). This
is equivale'nt to 203,560 annual hours for 14,000 participating house-
holds. The implicit wage equals $7.09 per hour.
dDeduct 19.7 minutes per month from 72.7 minutes of total monthly
household source separation. Thus, 14,000 participating households at
53 minutes per month gives 148,400 annual total hours in home preparation
of recyclables. The implicit wage equals $7.09 per hour.
96
[
c
[
[
~~
L
r-~
r_a
h
L
[
l __ :
I
I .
[
[
n L~
[
r:
L
[J
l:d
r E
J_:
L
r·
the cowuunity would be better off by expanding tbe product mix and
enlarging the aggregate level of material recovery despite evidence
of substantial commercial losses. In other words, co~~ercial gains
realized under conditions of r~stricted product mix do not compensate
for the extra social costs of reducing aggregate recovery from original
basic scenario levels.
The configuration of costs and benefits outlined in Table 4-ll
reflects fairly restrictive assumptions about the impact of recycling.
For example, the non-market benefits that I have quantified do not
include the amenity value of reducing litter and pollution from re-
cycling, nor does the table consider the resulting potential reductions
in refuse collection.
On the other hand, the non-market costs of separating and deliver-
ing household waste may_conceivably be incorporated into everyday house-
hold chores and overlapping errands. Thus, the figures in Table 4-11
tend to understate net social benefits. The extent to which this occurs
·depends partly on the relative importance one places on competing bene-
fits and costs.
A more favorable evaluation of social feasibility would be re-
fleeted under the following assumptions:
1. Home separation and delivery impose negligible costs on
the average resident who participates in recycling.
2. The volume of recycling assumed in the basic scenario ±s·
sufficient to reduce the frequency of municipal refuse
collection and, therefore, to lower refuse collection costs.
97
Returning to Table 2-11, we note that of the $2.6 million in
annual total municipal refuse collection costs approximately $1.4
million is needed to cover costs of labor, supplies, equipment rental,
and repairs and maintenance .. By definition, these costs vary with the
frequency of collection. If we assume that the frequency of collection [
and the variable components of collection cost fall in proportion to
the decline in the quantity of mixed solid waste collected by the
municipality, then material recovery in the basic scenario reduces the [
variable components of annual collection cost by 4 percent, or $56,000.
The restricted product mix in the basic scenario reduces variable col-
lection costs by 2 percent, or $28,000. n L_c
The effects on external benefits and costs of more favorable I
assumptions on recycling are presented in Table 4-12. This results in L.
·positive net social benefits in both recycling scenarios. Note the
trend in net social benefits and costs and external benefits and costs
pert~ining to raspective l~vels of r~cov~ry ~n both b~sic ~nd modifiad B
basic scenarios.
In the basic scenario, net external benefits exceed commercial
losses and generate social benefits of $4.05 per ton. Under conditions
of restricted product mix, the combination of private income and public
benefits yield net social benefits equivalent to $36.54 per ton.
Two general results emerge from the analysis of social feasibility ~
L
under changing assumptions. First, the elimination of residents'
L
98
--~
u
~
L
r :
L
Table 4-12. Social Feasibility Under Assumptions
More Favorable to Recycling
External Costs
Residential Fuel Consumption
Source Separation
·Total External Costs
External Benefits
Processing and Disposal
Landfill Longevity
Collection
Total External Benefits
Net External Benefits (Costs)
Net Commercial Income (Loss)
Net Social Benefits (Costs)
Net Social Benefits (Cost) Per Ton
99
Basic
6,624 Tons
$ 0
0
$ 0
$ 71,076
7,286
56,000
$134,362
$134,362
(107 '54 7)
$ 26,815
$ 4.05
Basic, Excluding Glass,
Mixed Scrap and CC
2,716 Tons
$ 0
0
$ 0
$29,143
2,988
28,000
$60 '131
$60,131
39,100
$99,231
$ 36.54
waste separation costs is the major reason that the external and
social benefits are positive in both scenarios. Thus, household waste
separation that is carried out effectively at minimum inconvenience
to the household improves the f.easibility of recycling by reducing the
level of external costs and by increasing the quantity of recovery
per unit of time and effort.
Second, as shown in Figure 4-1, the spread of net social benefits
and costs generated by changing the definition of externalities de-
creases as the quantity of materials recovered increases. Although
net social benefits per ton decline under the favorable interpretation
of externalities, a greater quantity of aggregate recovery reduces the
recycling recovery system's sensitivity to unfavorable circumstances,
such as inefficient and costly methods of waste separation in either the
residential or CO~uercial sector.
A principal feature of the basic recycling scenario is the absence
of any type of buyback policy to encourage participation and increase
material recovery. Material recovery in the basic scenario depended
on consumer donations. In the recycling industry, both systems are
practiced. Portland Recycling Team (PRT), a large, non-profit, full-
line recycling center in Portland, Oregon, recycles over 8,000 tons
·annually, enjoys $400,000 in revenues from sales, and does not have a
buyback policy. In contrast to PRT, Seattle Recycling, Inc. (SRI)
is profit-oriented and buys back most recyclables from consumers.
100
c
[
[
F
B
~
L
L
-
h ~ =
[
I :
Figure 4-1. A Comparison of the Range ~f Net Social
Benefits Between the Basic Scenario and the
Basic Scenario with Modified Product Mix
Net Social
Benefits
Per Ton
Net Social
Costs
Per Ton
0
$4
$229
Basic Scenario
101
$37
$373
Basic Scenario
excluding glass,
mixed scrap, and CC
SRI experiences about the same volume of busines~ and level of sales
as PRI. Both outfits retain the status of full-line recycling centers.
To determine the probable .effect of a buy-back policy or recycling
potential,·I assume that the recycling center in the basic scenario is
a profit enterprise and does not recover unprofitable materials such
as glass, CC, and mixed scrap. Consequently, the buy-back scenario
is identical to the basic scenario under the restricted product mix,
except for the buy-back policy itself. The materials are purchased
from the user, except for kraft paper, \.Jhich is accepted without
payment. Prices are shovm in Table 4-13 and reflect prices actually
offered by Anchorage-based recycling centers.
Haterial
Newsprint
Tin f:;:ms
Aluminum Cans
CPO
TAB
Kraft
Table 4-13. Buy-back Policy
Cash Payment/Pound
1¢.
]
15
2
4
Accept no payment
Cash Payment/Ton
$20
20
300
40
80
Note that prices in Table 4-13 are essentially the same as the average
buy-back prices in Seattle.
Commercial Feasibility. The introduction of a buy-back policy
increases variable operating costs in the modified basic scenario by
the value of disbursements to customers for materials purchased. The
102
[
-[
[
[
[
f'
L
[
fl L
r-:
G
F
lJ
G -.
[
__ j
' -I-
!
I'
t
L
cost of material purchases would be $83,740, raising total annual costs
28 percent from $300,203 to $383,673. If the buy-back policy does not
increase citizen participation beyond a level of !,715 annual tons of
recovered material, then the c~nditions for commercial feasibility
would no longer be satisfied. In order to generate sufficient earnings
to cover the additional costs of materials purchased, the quantity of
annual recovery would have to increase 34 percent to 3,638 tons. This
implies that citizen participation in newsprint, kraft paper, tin, alu-
minum, CPO, and tab card recovery would have to increase from 25 to
34 percent (18, 690 households), '"hich, from the standpoint of national
participation in home separation, represents an upper limit of achieve-
ment and is probably unlikely to immediately occur in Anchorage where
household waste separation and commercial recycling are just undenvay.
Thus, the responsiveness of consumers to buy-back incentives is an
important determinant of commercial feasibility in the buy-back scenario.
Returning to the Portland and Seattle examples, we note that with nine
years of recycling experience depending entirely on consumer donations
of recyclables, Portland Recycle Team incurred consecutive annual losses
of approximately $20,000 in both fiscal 1978 and 1979, in spite of
receiving v.rell over $100,000 in annual grants and non-revenue, sup'ple-
mentary income (e.g., CETA and work study) over the same period. Under
similar conditions, Seattle Recycling, Inc., was able to generate suf-
-ficient community involvement through its buy-back program to break even
or realize commercial profits.
103
Social feasibilitv. Assuming a constant pc.rticipation (25 percent),
a buy-back policy has no effect on the level of social feasibility in
the basic scenario under assumptions of restricted product mix. 11 Buy-
back" represents a transfer from the private to the public sector with-
out introducing an economic gain or loss to the community as a whole.
By distributing funds to the public sector, a buy-back program does
compensate for non-market, household waste separation and delivery costs
under a more pessimistic interpretation of external benefits and costs.
As shmm in Table 4-14, raising the rate of participation to
reach a break-even level of material recovery in the buy-back scenario
would not substantially affect net social benefits or costs per ton.
Office Paper Collection Scenario
In this case, the buy-back recycling scenario is modified to
include office waste paper recovery. We assume that the State of Alaska
And Nnnicipality of Anchorage mandate that all office employees sepa-
rate high-grade white and colored ledger paper for recycling. In 1978,
8 ·17,195 professional and technical employees generated approximately
3,070 tons 9 of mixed office paper. This averages out to about 1 pound
a day per employee.
8 Ender, 1978.
9 office paper constitutes 3.4 percent of total waste paper entering
landfill disposal (GAAB, 1975).
104
r
[
c
1:3
[
r L:
-
[
1:
L
~
8
a=
L
L
Table 4-14. Net Sociala Benefits and Costs in.the Buy-back Scenario
Under Alternate Assumptions on Participation and on
Interpretation of Non-market Benefits and Costs
Interpretation of
Non-market Benefits
and Costs Participation
Restrictive
c Favorable
25% (2,716 Tons)
($1.01 Million),d
($373/ton)
e $99,000, $37/ton
aCombined private and public sector returns.
bBreakeven commercial recovery.
34%b (3,638 Tons)
($1. 33 million),
($364/ton)
$158,000, $43/ton
cExclude home separation and delivery costs. Include refuse
collection cost reductions due to 2 percent decline in total municipal
refuse collection.
d Table 4-ll.
e Table 4-12.
105
[
Currently, there are approxinately 10,000 s·tate and local government
employees in Anchorage. I assume that each employee generates l pound ·[
each of recoverable white and colored ledger paper per week. This
amounts t·o a total of 500 total. tons per year from state and local [
public offices. [
The implementation of office wastepaper separation introduces two
basic logistics requirements in addition to a general commitment by all
employees. First, source separation trays would be required for most
office desks. Larger, centrally located containers would also be
required for office workers to deposit their daily accumulation of
separated wastepaper. Second, the daily accumulation of office paper
r,
L_;
would have to be collected from each centrally located office container
and deposited at the loading areas for pickup by a recycle center
collection truck. The second task could be accomplished by employees c:
L
until janitorial contracts were modified (Dick Stokes, DEC).
In this analysis, I ignore the cost of separation wastepaper
·trays and containers, which could be financed through receipts from
wastepaper sales to the recycler. Also, I note no attempt to cal-
culate the value of time and effort of employee participation in source
separation. For all intents and purposes, the impact of wastepaper
separation on office emplo;~ent would be negligible.
In order to accommodate office wastepaper collection and processing, t::
L
the recycle center would have to modify plant capacity, equipment, and
L
106
___ J
...
~ ~
[ .
f 0
L
personnel, as well as make adjustments in operating costs and revenues.
These adjustments are outlined in Table 4-15 and are derived from speci-
fications used consistently throughout this report .
The recycle center would be responsible for daily collection from
office buildings. Separated office wastepaper would be returned to the
warehouse, checked for contaminants, baled, and loaded directly on a
standby container. Two containerloads would be shipped each month.
I assume that high-grade office ledger paper would be purchased
from rPApPrtive offices. The recycle center would pay 2 cents per
pound for white ledger paper ($40/ton) and 1 cent per pound for colored
ledger paper.
Implementation of office source separation and collection may be
carried out informally as it is currently exercised, in connection with
computer paper, or under contractual agreement in which case public
agencies solicit bids for collection and payback from recyclers.
Commercial Feasibilitv
In this example, high-grade office paper recovery is integrated
into the previous buy-back scenario. The effect of office waste paper
recovery on commercial feasibility is compared to the original buy-back
scenario in a summary statement of revenues and expenses in Table 4-16.
107
Table 4-15. Operation and Equipment Requirements
for 500 Tons of Annual Office Paper Recovery
Annual Operation
Revenue
1\ihite Ledger 250 Tons @ $180/ton
Color Ledger 250 tons @ $125/ton
Materials Purchase
White Ledger @ $40/ton
Colored Ledger @ $20/ton
Personnel
Driver (l)
Sorter (l)
Freight
2 containers/month @ $566 each
Collection
45,000
31,250
10,000
5,000
20,700
9,600
Trucking (fuel, maintenance, and insurance)
Plant and Equipment
·Plant
500 square feet additional @ .40/ft 2
Equipment
Truck (l) 12' bed, enclosed, used
Bins (6)' 3 yd3
108
4,500
859
$ 76,250
15,000
30,300
l3 ,584
3,840
2,400
5,359
[
[
[
I'
b
B
I=
L
L
I=
L
Table 4-16. Su:-;:mary Statement of Revenues· and Expenses for
Buy-back and Buy-back Plus Office Paper Scenarios
Quantity Recovered
Revenue
voc
Haterials Purchased
Collection
Processing
Freight
Total VOC
Buv-back
2,716 tons
$339,303
83,740
33,671
40,050
71,022
$229,253
Gross Operating Profit $110,820
FOC
Harehouse
Administration
Overhead
Total FOC
Total Operating Costs
Operating Surplus
(Deficit)
Capital Recovery Cost
Annual Total Costs
Annual Net Income
(Loss)
24,000
79,925
40,905
$144,830
$373,313
$ (34, 010)
10,630
383,943
$(44,640)
109
Buy-back Plus
Office Source
Separation
3,216 tons
$415,553
98,740
58,211
49,650
84., 606
$291,207
$124,346
26,400
79,925
44,995
$151,320
$442,527
$(26,974)
12,237
454,764
$(39,211)
Dollars Per Ton
in Office
Source Separation
129.21
90.55
(12.19)
Social Feasibilitv. Under a restrictive interpretation of non-
market benefits and costs, the addition of 500 tons of high-grade
office ledger would reduce net social costs in the buy-back scenario
from $1.01 million to $986 thousand. As sho\~ in Table 4-17, net social
costs per ton would decline 18 percent from $373 to $307. Thus, although
the office paper collection scenario is not cost effective, from the
standpoint of social feasibility the community would realize significant
reductions in net social costs with each additional ton of office paper
recovered. These savings would result from several factors which dis-
tinguish the buy-back and office paper collection scenarios. Most
notably, office ,,rastepaper separation ,,rould be confined to the commercial
or institutional sector and would not raise external costs of home
separation and delivery. Also, the office paper collection scenario
would result in less commercial losses (Table 4-16) and greater disburse-
ments to the public sector for material purchased.
T~rlPr A mnrP nptimistir intPrprPtAtinn nf PXtPrnAl hPnPfits Anrl
costs, office paper separation and collection would raise net social
benefits from the original level in the buy-back scenario without office
paper collection. However, the increase in net social benefits is less
per ton ($2) than the decrease in net social costs under the pessimistic
interpretation of public sector benefits and costs ($66 per ton). The
discrepancy occurs because the pessimistic interpretation of exter-
nalities incorporates household waste separation costs while the op-
timistic interpretation does not. Consequently, even though office
paper collection does not affect the residential sector, and therefore
110
[
[
[,.-,
__ _j
[
L
[
I'
L
I=
L
L:
...
r
b!
L
Table 4-17. Comparison of Net Sociala Benefits and Costs
in the Buy-back and Office Source Separation Scenarios
Interpretation of
Non-market' Benefits
and Costs
Restricted
Favorablec
b Buy-back
(2,716 tons)
($1.01 million),
($373/ton)
$99,000, $37/ton
Scenario
Office Source Separation
(3,216 tons)
($986,000), ($307 /ton)
$126,000, $39/ton
aCombined private and public sector returns.
b Table 4-14.
c Exclude home separation and delivery costs. Include refuse
collection cost reductions due to a 2 percent decline in total municipal
refuse collection.
111
the external cost of household collection, the constant level of total
external costs from the buy-back scenario is spread over a larger total
quantity of material recovery (buy-back plus office paper collection)
which reduces the average unit _cost (cost per ton) of household waste
separation·. Hhereas office paper collection increases public benefits
under both interpretations of externalities, external costs are absent
from the optimistic interpretation and, therefore, cannot undergo unit
reductions with increases in aggregate recovery.
Summary
We have examined three scenarios, each with a 25 percent partici-
pation in both commercial and residential sectors. All examples represent
full-line recycling (i.e., at least three different materials), although
some were more specialized than others. None of the three scenarios
demonstrated a waste-materials recovery plan that was able to break
even.
In the alternative buy-back scenario, the latitude of material
recovery is restricted to include only those materials exhibiting a
positive return after deducting material-specific variable operating
expenses from revenue in the basic scenario. Nevertheless, a break-even
total revenue-total cost profile was not attained; instead, this plan
would require a 10 percent increase in residential and commercial
participation in order to generate enough secondary materials to
financially break even.
112
[
[
r·,
L
[
c
L
D
F tJ
~
L
L
I -
-L
This example illustrates the importance of citizen participation
in recycling. Even under conditions in ,,Thich participation in material
recovery is 2'i tim(">.s grPRtPr th;;m estimates of current Anchor;J.ge po.r-
ticipation (less than 1 percent), first-level, commercial feasibility
would not be attained. To some extent, the product mix configuration
would contribute to unprofitable recovery. h~en the product mix is
subsequently narrowed to eliminate all unprofitable secondary materials
(i.e., mixed scrap, glass, and CC), CO~uercial prospects improve mod-
estly but remain unprofitable. Recycling, under the modified-product
mix in the buy-back scenario, would be profitable only under conditions
in 'i.Jhich recyclables are donated by residents and commercial groups.
Citizen participation is therefore critical to the commercial viability
of full-line waste material recovery.
A buy-back policy can be expected to encourage participation and
increase the rate of material recovery. Yet, the cost of purchasing
secondary materials from users would absorb 25 percent of gross reve
nues and weigh heavily against commercial implementation, particularly
under circumstances in which the effect of buy-back is not a clear
10 factor in developing incentives to recycle.
We also examined the consequences of instituting a program in
state and local offices wherein office employees would collect and
10Again, I refer to the Portland Recycling Team (PRT) and Seattle
Recycling, Inc. (SRI). In contrast to SRI, PRT depends on customer·
donations of all ~ecyclables. Nevertheless, PRT and SRI share parallel
structural features, including capacity and actual volume recovered.
113
separate high-grade ledger paper for recycling. ·under the assumptions
made, the program \vould not have broken even financially, although the
economics improved somewhat over the buy-back scenario. In this par-
ticular example, more than twice the increase in office paper separation
alone (as opposed to an across-the-board proportionate increase in all
materials) would be required to cover the annual cost of collecting and
processing, as well as losses incurred in the original buyback scenario,
which incorporates office wastepaper separation.
Thus, although the level of participation, and therefore the
quantity of recyclables available for recovery, is a necessary condition
for cost-effective recycling, the mix of secondary materials selected
for recovery is also an important determinant of commercial breakeven
potential.
"Hidden" benefits and costs outside of private sector exchange are
Rlqn rnnsirlPrPrl in thP AnAlysis. Tn nrrlPr tn rlPtPrminP thP sPnsitivity
of material recycling to different interpretations of external benefits,
both a pessimistic and an optimistic benefit-cost analysis of each
recycling scenario are performed. Under the pessimistic interpretation,
social costs not reflected in market prices include fuel consumption
costs for resident delivery of recyclables to the recycle center and the
cost of time and effort in household waste separation.
If labor invested in home separation of recyclables represents
labor time that would otherwise be used in leisure or in work, then
114
[
[
[
,--;
~
[
0
L
.
l__;
[
r~
L
[
~ L
l
-;;.;c.ste sepc.ration has an opportunity cost and must be priced accordingly.
The average seco;_ .. 1d quc.rter Anchorage '"age rate ($7. 09) is used for this
purpose .::<.nd results in snbst.:::ntia1 implicit labor costs.
On the other hand, the nature of household waste separation allows
it to be easily integrated into routine household functions and helps
alert consumers to the inefficiencies of excessive producer packaging
and the more general waste flow problem. To some extent, waste separa-
tion can actually reduce the frequency of garbage chores and ultimately
the cost of garbage collection. Thus, applying a market wage rate to
Llt::c: !:;):Jelll: sep2.1:2ting re;cyclatles oa.y unfavorably overstate hidden
(non-market) costs of recycling.
The cost of fuel used in residential delivery of recyclables to
district drop-off depots or to the recycle center represents a relevant
social cost. However, it is likely that these deliveries will be com-
bined with other errands and the costs sprRad accordingly.
Thus, the optimistic interpretation of external costs ignores
estimates of residential deliv_ery and household \·:c.ste separation. The
community realizes direct social benefits through reduced costs related
to garbage processing and disposal, as well as landfill site development.
I estimate that on the average each recycled ton of waste saves $11.83
in waste management costs, excluding the cost of refuse collection .
Both the pessimistic and optimistic interpretations of external benefits
include these cost reductions in solid waste management. Under the
115
assumption that recycling can also reduce refus~ collection costs, the
relaxed benefit/cost profile includes a measure of refuse collection
savings based on reductions in collection frequency.
Several qualitative benefits are absent from the interpretation c
of external, non-market factors. They include aesthetic and other
benefits resulting from reduced pollution, litter, and waste; such L
benefits are subjective and therefore difficult to measure. By omit-
ting these benefits, I do not intend to undervalue their importance, [
but rather leave their relative significance to individual interpreta-
tion. Also, I assume that the benefits of energy conservation are fully
reflected in rising market prices.
The social (i.e., public and private) benefits calculated above
are understated to the extent that physical amenities related to the
environment are positive and energy savings are ignored in market
prices.
Table 4-18 summarizes the effect of competing definitions of
external benefits and costs in connection with the basic, buy-back, and
office paper separation scenarios. In each of these scenarios, net
external benefits are realized only under the optimisti~ interpretation
of non-market benefits and costs for all scenarios. In the pessimistic
interpretation, the cost of separating recyclables in the home contrib-
utes importantly to the resulting unfavorable benefit/cost profiles.
Note that under either benefit/cost interpretation, the office paper
116
,, I . !.~ l... ~
Table L1-l8. ·comparc::tivc Benefit/Cost Summary o[ Hccycling Scennr:Los
UndEr Alternate Interpretations of Externnl Benefits and Costs
Commercial Income
(loss)
Net External Benefits
(costs)
Net Social Benefits
(costs)
Net External Benefits
(costs)
Net Social Benefits
(costs)
Basic (6,6~4 tons)
Dollars $ Per Ton
(107,547) ( 16 )
(1,407,026) ( 212 )
(1,514, 7ld) ( 229 )
134,36~ 20
26,815 4
Office Paper
Buyback (2 LZ..:l6 to:..:.lc.:..:1s=-<) ___ ~S.:::..cpara tion (3 1 2] 6_.-~~~~:71
DoLLars DolL:n:s
(44,640) ( 16 ) (39, 211) ( 1.2 )
PESSINISTIC INTERPRETATION
(967,694) ( 356 ) (946,780)
(1,012,334) ( 373 ) (985,991) ( 307 )
OPTIMISTIC INTERPRETATION
lll3, 871 53 164,785 51
99,231 37 125,574 39
l ..
collection scenario, in contrast to the basic scenario, demonstrates the
highest social benefits and the lowest social costs, even though its
total material recovery is 50 percent less.
The tradeoff between commercial and social feasibility is illus-
trated in the context of glass recycling in the basic and buy-back
scenarios. In the basic scenario, requirements for extra capital
investment, handling, and shipping for glass (and to a lesser extent,
mixed scrap and CC) would absorb positive income-generating potential
from other recyclables and severely disrupt the co~~ercial viability
of the over.sll recovery prnt;rPm. Thns, t;lr~ss v,;r~s snhsPcJnPntly v,;ith-
drawn from consideration in the profit-making, buy-back scenario.
Returning to Table 4-8, we note that unit variable operating costs
(i.e., variable operating costs per ton) in glass recovery exceed
unit revenue potential by $6.55 per ton. That is, the recycler
loses $6.55 for every ton of cullet that is .recovered and marketed.
Tn r~rldition to operating costs. costs allocated to ilass recovery
equipment in the basic scenario would be about $58,000, or one-third
of total basic scenario equipment costs. The annual capital recovery·
cost for glass collection and processing equipment would reduce to
$8.60 per ton and increase the operating deficit from $6.55 to $1~.15
for each ton recycled. From the standpoint of commercial feasibility,
the high cost of equipment, processing, and shipping would contribute
to unfavorable conditions in glass recovery.
118
[
[
['
[
1:
L
n
LJ .
J::
L
L
-
[
~
IJ
L
L
Hovever, under the relaxed interpretation of external benefits
and costs, 2,030 tons of glass recovery would generate $41,320, or
$20.35 per ton in net external benefits. Thus, by eliminating glass
recovery,· the reduction in comm.ercial losses ($15 .15 per ton) l·muld not
compensate·for the total value of foregone benefits--$20.35. From the
standpoint of more comprehensive social feasibility, glass recycling in
the basic scenario is socially desirable.
In contrast to glass recovery, mixed scrap paper and CC incur
com.c11ercial losses (even ignoring equipment costs) that exceed public
sector gains. Thus, rPryrling th~se two materials does not satisfy
the formal condition for social feasibility. Net social costs equal
$.92 and $28.02 per ton for mixed scrap and CC, respectively.
119
120
[
[
r~
[
[
[~
[
Q
-n
L
[
I
L
[
L
PART V. P"C:SLIC POLICY .
In the preceding sections, we examined the nature of material
throughput in Anchorage, the co_st of solid waste management, the current
extent of recycling, and a few carefully constructed, expanded recycling
scenarios to determine '>.Jhether or not sufficient conditions exist in
Anchorage to '''arrant greater private or public sector involvement in
recycling.
There are currently at least a dozen profit and nonprofit, Anchorage-
quantity of material recovery includes 250,000 gallons of waste oil,
250 tons of waste paper, and 9,000 tons of scrap metal. By weight,
material recovery is equivalent to 4 percent of total mixed, solid waste
entering landfill disposal (160,084 tons in 1979). Until the reservoir
of recoverable secondary materials is exploited further, the disposal of
secondary materials \vill absorb landfill space at a rate of 16 acres per
l year.
The quantity of material throughput and the modest extent of cur-
rent recycling activity in Anchorage suggests that substantial untapped
reserves of recyclable material are available for immediate recovery. I
conservatively estimate that out of 30,000 tons waste paper, glass, and
1 Assuming the Hunicipal refuse shredder is operating (see discussion
of solid waste management in Part II).
121
[
tin and aluminum cans that are readily availabl~ for recovery (excluding
[
the segment involved in heavy metals recovery), only about 2 percent are
actually recycled. The remaining tonnage is destined for landfill
disposal. c
In constructing our recycling scenarios, He have borrov.1ed from the
[
experience of active recyclers in Anchorage (notably the Alaska Center
for the Environment Recycle Center) and from ongoing recycling recovery
systems in the Pacific Northwest. However, even under circumstances in [
which community participation in source-separation of recyclables would
he :=mbsti'lntiAJ ly greater than current participation in Anchorage, none
of the recycling scenarios was able to achieve net positive income based
upon strict commercial cost accounting without government assistance.
In order to break even financially, collli'1lercial recyclers would have
to either increase the quantity of wastes recovered to match the upper
1 imi ts of >.:rhat a well-developed program of community participation could 6
achieve or restrict the range of material recovery to more valuable,
high-grade materials that are capable of generating positive commercial
returns at the expense of an overall reduction in material recovery. In
general, the scenario results suggest that a broad-based, full-time re-
cycling recovery system in Anchorage cannot occur without state involvement.
Whether or not the state should become involved in policies to
stimulate recycling depends partially upon how we define external
benefits and costs used to evaluate effects of recycling on the public
L
.122
_J
r
6
L
sector. The recycling scenario results suggest that the economic inter-
pretation of household waste separation is the most significant factor
in determining net external benefits and costs. If, for example, the
time and effort spent in househ.old waste separation of recyclables is
interpreted to be at the expense of leisure or employment (and is priced
accordingly), then home separation imposes net external costs on the
Anchorage community in all recycling scenarios. Thus, under the
"pessimistic" interpretation of costs and benefits, negative returns in
the public sector would compound commercial losses and net social costs
\,,ould prevail.
On the other hand, if waste separation is interpreted as a routine
household function that stimulates compensating reductions in other
household chores (e.g., reduced garbage accumulation) and, therefore,
does not impose extra costs on residents, then recycling could have
net social benefits in connection with the same recycling scenarios
after accounting for lns&PS in thP privAtP sPrtnr. Th11R, in thP npti-
mistic interpretation of external benefits and costs, public sector
·gains would more than compensate for commerci&l losses. These condi-
tions \vould then justify government subsidy.
Yet the relationship between the quantity of material recovered
and the level of net social benefits is not clearcut. A comparison of
recycling scenario results suggests that the level of net social benefits
is affected not only by total quantity of a material recovered but also
by the particular combination of materials recovered (i.e. product mix)
123
as ~ell. For example, in Table 4-18, under the optimistic interpretation
of externalities, the basic scenario has a wider product mix and a larger
quantity of materials recovered but has less net social benefits than
either of the alternate recycl~ng scenarios. As sho~~ in Figure 5-l,
the discrepancy occurs because recycling certain materials is socially
beneficial but commercially unprofitable; recycling of other materials
would be unprofitable from both a commercial and social standpoint.
Public policy must, therefore, accommodate tradeoffs in private
and public sector benefits for materials that do not economically satisfy
both commercial and social criteria. Policy proposals that stimulate
private sector recovery without regard to product mix considerations
may omit materials that are socially beneficial. Glass recovery is a
case in point. Basic scenario results indicate that the cost of equip-
ment, handling, and freight would exceed private benefits. Cost reduc-
tions in solid-waste management and landfill site development, ho~ever,
~.7nuld £1?nPrf'ltP pnc;i tivP rPtnrns in thP pnhl i r sPrtor th11t ont~.;rPi gh
2 public sector losses from glass recovery.
Conversely, public policy that is confined to a commercially un-
profitable product mix but satisfies the conditions for social feasibility
may relinquish the opportunity to produce additional net social benefits.
Recall, for example, that the Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle
2 Glass is a major component of roadside litter and is considerably
less biodegradable than either aluminum or tin cans. Thus, public bene-
fits from glass recovery are understated by the value of litter reduction
amenities from recycling.
124
[
[
r,
\'_ __ ~
t .
L
r~
~
r
t:
r
b
L
Social
Feasibility
Figure 5-l. Product Mix Mairixa
Commercial Feasibility
Positive Negative
newsprint, kraft,
CPO, tab cards, glass
Positive tin cans,
aluminum cans
I
I
cc,
Negative mixed scrap
-
aFrom basic scenario, using favorable interpretation of externalities.
Center has incurred commercial losses in CPO, tab cards, and ne\,'Sprint.
Those losses, according to basic scenario results, would become com-
mercial gains when the scale of recovery is increased.
Also,· if the calculation of external benefits does not include the
benefits realized from reducing litter and pollution, as well as other
benefits not recognized explicitly (e.g. energy conservation and reduced
rates of nonrenewable resource depletion), then net social benefits will
be understated. Consequently, materials not satisfying quantitative
conditions may still be socially beneficial from a broader interpreta-
tion of externA] benefits from recycling.
In addition to the total quantity of material recovery, the level
of net social benefits implied by a specific product mix, and the defini-
tion of externalities, some important non-economic factors enter into
policy design. The existing recycling recovery system in Anchorage
~onsists of several independent, specialized, small-scale, profit and
nonprofit recyclers that compete vigorously for supplies of available
·secondary materials that are limited in part by a relatively low rate
of citizen participation. The potential economic gain from public
intervention that leads to direct competition with private recyclers
would decline by an amount equivalent to the value of foregone private
material recovery displaced by direct public intervention.
The objective of public policy is to increase material recovery in
order that the community may realize economic and non-economic benefits
126
[
[
·[
[
[
[
[
~~
LJ
D
Ll
[
[
[
r
b
r
b
t::
L
I~,
from recycling. Ultimately, the primary source ·of material recovery is
derived from citizen participation. Citizen participation is an impor-
tant determinant of scale economies to the recycler and, therefore,
represents a key goal of publi~ policy. Policies to stimulate citizen
participation would indirectly affect the recycling recovery sector
without the potentially harmful effects of direct government interfer-
ence in the market.
Policy Proposals
Several policy proposals are examined in this section. The selec-
tion of policies is designed to represent a broad range of policy options
but is not intended to exhaust all the possibilities. The policies pre-
sented illustrate several economic and non-economic tradeoffs and pro-
vide guidelines for policy design. Two general policy classifications
are explored: those that affect the recyclipg recovery system directly
and those that are directed toward stimulating citizen participation
and therefore affect the recovery sector indirectly.
Once the policy maker determines a target quantity and composition
of material recove~y, the corresponding level of net social benefits
provides guidelines for the socially desirable level of public invest-
ment in recycling.
127
[
The following policy options are reviewed and evaluated fro~ the
standpoint of private sector response, impact on material recovery, and
cost to the State of Alaska. They are:
Recycling Recovery Sector
Subsidy
[
Central recovery wholesaler [
Depletion deduction
Tax credit
Community Participation
Compulsory office paper separation
Returnable beverage container legislation
Recycling Recovery Sector
Subsidy. Subsidization can be implemented on two general levels.
The State may either appropriate start-up funds for a large-scale, non-
profit, full-line recycler or establish a grant program designed to
·distribute smaller amounts of funds to numerous private organizations
involved in material recovery.
The purpose behind concentrating state support on a single recycler
is to establish an overall scale of material recovery that captures
important economies not otherwise attainable. Economies of scale would
then permit a product mix that includes less profitable materials that
would typically not be handled by private, profit-motivated recyclers.
L
128
___ _j
I~
L
[
r-~ c
h
L
L
This is an important consideration since Anchorc.ge-based organizations
involved in material recovery generally specialized in one or t>,•o com-
mercially favorable materials and, under the present circumstances, are
unlikely to contribute signific?ntly to the objective of comprehensive
material recovery.
The small, independent, private collectors whom I interviewed in
the course of collecting information on local recycling effort all
expressed concern over direct State intervention of this type. In their
view, public start-up assistance unconditionally discriminates against
their effort to compete effectively, particularly if a nonprofit:, pub-
licly-funded recycler purchases materials from users and, in so doing,
captures some of their business.
To minimize the adverse effect of public intervention in the private
sector, the State could prohibit the subsidized recycle center from
p11rrhRsing materials that are openly purchased by other private col-
lectors. Yet, without buy-back incentives, a State-assisted, "full-
line" recycle center may experience limited success in attracting source-
separated materials--especially more centralized commercial sources of
high-grade CPO, tab· cards, and ledger paper. The State could compromise
moderately and allow the subsidized recycle center to purchase recyclables
from nonprofit organizations only. This is, in fact, the present policy
followed by the Alaska Center for the Environment Recycle Center. Although
it is met with considerable dissatisfaction by private recyclers, it does
represent a more equitable arrangement from the standpoint of direct,
129
private-sector interference. As an additional cbndition, the subsidy
could be contingent on the recycler accepting a carefully specified,
broad range of materials. The financial latitude provided from public
support creates an opportunity ~o introduce socially beneficial, yet
commercially unprofitable, materials into the product mix and to innovate
techniques in collection, separation, compaction, and transportation.
Under conditions of prohibited buyback, financial assistance can be used
to fund educational programs designed to stimulate participation.
To reduce the potentially harmful effects of direct public inter-
vention, the State could decentralize its involvement by issuing a
limited number of moderate-size grants to recyclers. This, however,
does not eliminate the problem of unfair competition and of animosity
developing between subsidized and nonsubsidized recyclers. To protect
the interests of those not receiving grants, and to increase the poten-
tial for broader range of secondary material recovery, the State could
reqnire that subsidized recyclers accept (without pavment) certain less
profitable materials. The recycler would stockpile these materials
·until sufficient mass is accumulated to raise a commercial profit, or
until the cost of storage exceeds freight costs, whichever occurs first.
The grant would absorb commercial losses related to unprofitable mater-
ials. In addition to increasing the overall quantity of materials
recovered, public funds would increase the individual recycler's scale
of recovery ·and potentially reduce certain unit operating costs (e. g.
the cost of collection, of bundling, or of freight per ton).
130
r L,
b
[
[J
J
L
I would expect a qualitative difference in rartge of materials
recovered under the decentralized program of public support in compari-
son to the case of a larget lump-sum appropriation to a nonprofit, full-
line recycler. For example, m~derate-scale glass recovery (2,030 tons
per year or 13 percent of feasible recovery) requires $58,000 in equip-
ment alone and would, therefore, be implemented only under the large,
lump-sum appropriation.
In either case, the level of subsidization would be a function of
projected participation, the composition of material recovery, the cost
of attaining that level of recovery, and the level of direct net social
[ benefits (i.e. solid waste management savings less resident delivery
[ costs).
Results from the basic and buy-back scenarios may be used as pre-
liminary guidelines to determine the level of subsidization for respective
Several economic parameters are presented in Table 5-l as subsidy
guidelines. Annual commercial operating losses reflect the ongoing
economic burden of'material recovery in the private sector; the actual
losses that would be reported in financial statements. Total capital
investment is an estimate of required startup expenditures. Note that
·commercial operating losses subsume annual capital recovery costs to
reflect the cost of debt incurred in coFmercial money markets to finance
L
equipment. Net social benefits reflect the combination of ongoing
L 131
private and public sector benefits and costs and. indicate the implicit
cost to the community of not expanding material recovery for recycling.
By construction, net social benefits reflect only direct net benefits
of material recovery to the Ancporage community and not the broader
consequences of recycling itself.
Table 5-l. Subsidy Guidelinesa
Annual Commerciald Total Net
Subsidv Program Operating Losses CaEital Investment Social Benefits
Full-line b $108,000 $147,000 $29,000
Decentralizedc $45,000 $35,000 $99,000
aAssuming 25 percent participation.
bB . S . as1c cenar1o. c Buy Back.
dCommercial operating losses include annual capital recovery costs
(i.e., debt service, depreciation).
Circumstances in the basic scenario reflect those of·a nonprofit,
full-line recycler under a policy of prohibited buyback. Therefore,
:1c E:hmm in Table 5-l, I apply b:1cic t::cenario n:.cultc :1c guidolinoc
for lump-sum subsidization of a single, full-line recycler. Alter-
natively, the buy-back scenario reflects a narrower range of more spe-
cialized, high-grade material recovery. Buy-back scenario results are
used to determine the aggregate level of decentralized public assistance
132
L
[
r
L
~
L
E
r B
~
L
J :
L
for several swaller-scale reyclers. I implicitly assume that 25 percent
citizen participation is achieved in each recycling program.
Central recovery wholesaler. As an alternative to direct subsidi-
zation of independent, profit or nonprofit recyclers, the state could
subsidize a central wholesaler/processor that would be impowered to
accept secondary materials without pay~ent to individuals or to pay
existing small collectors for unprocessed shipments. The recovery
wholesaler-would operate as an intermediary between collectors that
comprise the Anchorage-based recycling reccvery system and "stateside"
dPalers and secondary materials users that otherwise trade directly
with Anchorage collectors.
Several trade arrangements between the recovery wholesaler and
local collectors are possible. For example, the subsidy could, in part,
be used to raise payments for secondary materials from levels represent-
ing private sector values to levels that include net social benefits of
recycling. Under this arrangement, local collectors share in at least
some of the net social benefits. Even without price supports, howevEr,
local collectors would no longer incur the cost of shipping materials to
stateside markets and, in some cases, the cost of handling and pr0cessing
certain materials. For example, the total unit cost of collecting,
handling, and shipping processed glass to Seattle is about $45 per ton,
including glass-related capital costs, properly allocated. A market
price of $30 per ton produces a cmmuercial loss equal to $15 per ton
and is slightly less than the unit cost of freight--$16. Thus, direct
133
trade with an &~chorage-based recovery wholesaler would eliminate the
local collector's shipping requirement and thereby establish a feasible
progrRm in local glass collection.
As an·alternative to explicit price support, the buy-back price
offered to the local collector could intentionally be kept more stable
than market prices of recovered materials to circumvent the seasonal and
cyclical ~atterns of totally market-responsive recycling operations.
In addition to improving the economic conditions for commercial
recovery of secondary materials, the central recovery wholesaler would
help preserve competition and avoid grant discrimination among small
collectors. Further, the small collector would be free to choose
whether or not to trade with the central recycler.
Although a subsidy would most likely be required to cover equipment
and a portion of oneoing operatine expenses, several economic benefits
would be available to the nonprofit, publicly-operated central recovery
·facility that would not be available to the small, independent collector.
Economies of scale in first-stage processing (shredding, baling, com-
pacting) and in transportation constitute the most important economic
benefits. Basic scenario results suggest that a ten-fold expansion of
newsprint, CPO, and tab card recovery from ACERC quarterly production of
54 tons reduces combined collection, processing, and transportation costs
50 percent, from $104 to $52 per ton. Although handling, processing,
and transportation costs depend on the specific physical characteristics
134
[
r
L_
h ~~
[
F w
c
I::!
~
L
L
__ _j
[
L
of each material, it is likely that these scale economies are representa-
tive of general conditions in secondary material recovery.
A central recovery wholesa~er that is capable of shipping consistently
larger, more homogeneous quantities of secondary materials would reduce
the dealer's uncertainty and lower the dealer's handling requirements.
Dealers often reward recyclers by sharing with them a portion of the
savings realized as a result of improvements in the quality, mass, and
consistency of shipments. Also, the large scale of recovery would place
the recovery wholesaler in a stronger bargaining position to negotiate
more favorahJ e terms of tr<'loe with deAlers or ser.onrlnry mAteriAls 11sP.rs.
Further, the recovery wholesaler would be able to more realistically
explore the potential for direct trade in international markets, notably
Japan, Taiwan, and Korea.
To illustrate the economic effects of a publicly subsidized
recovery wholesaler in Anchorage. the configuration of assumptions in
the basic scenario is applied jointly to a hypothetical recovery whole-
saler and to the set of independent, small-scale, secondary materials·
collectors. A comparative statement of annual revenues and expenses for
the recovery wholesaler and independent collectors is presented in·
Table 5-2 and is based on the following general assumptions:
1. The recovery wholesaler purchases materials from Anchorage-
based independent collectors at spot prices in Seattle
secondary materials markets and is unable to sell recovered
materials at a higher price than it pays.
135
Table 5-2. Comparative Statement of Annual Revenuesa
and Expenses for the Recovery Wholesaler
and Independent Collectors
Revenue
Variable Operating Cost (VOC)
Materials Purchased
Collection
Processing
Freight
Total VOC
Fixed Operating Costs (FOC)
Capital Recovery Costs (CRC)
Annual Total Costs
(VOC + FOC + CRC)
Net Income (Loss)
Recovery
1-.Tholesaler
463,000
463,000
92,000
159,000
714,000
133, ooob
55,000c
902,000
(439 ,000)
aFigures from basic recycling scenario.
Independent
Collectors
463,000
149,000
89,000
238,000
88,000d
28,000d
354,000
109,000
bSeventy-five percent of total FOC in the basic recycling scenario.
c One hundred percent of total CRC in the basic recycling sc~n~rio.
dFifty percent of total FOC and of total CRC in the basic recycling
scenario.
136
[
·[
c
[
[,
[,
c
J=;
L
L
-
I
~
L
2.
3.
Independent collectors purchase second~ry materials from
consumers. Th~ aggregate cost of materials purchases
from consumers equals $84,000 from the buy-back scenario,
covering newsprint, kraft, tin, aluminum, CPO, and tab
cards, plus $65,000 for beverage bottle buyback at about
one-half cent per bottle.
First-stage processing (sorting, shredding, baling, and
compacting) and transportation to secondary materials
markets are carried out by the recovery \.Jholesaler.
4. Independent collectors are responsible for servicing
consumer deliveries and collecting from co~~ercial
institutions. They incur the full collection costs
from the basic scenario--$89,000.
5. Fixed operating costs (FOC) and capital recovery costs
(CRC) are distributed betv;een the recovery v.rholesaler
and independent collectors such that the sum of each
exceeds estimated levels in the basic scenario. This
a£sumption insures that overlapping equipment, over-
head, and administrative costs are not overlooked.
Several observations emerge from the figures in Table 5-2. Net
coF~ercial losses equal those incurred by the recovery wholesaler
($439,000) less the aggregate private gain realized by independent
collectors _($109 ,000). Commercial feasibility is, therefore, not
satisfied.
Net external benefits from the basic scenario equal $134,000 and
do not cover net losses in the commercial sector. Thus, net social
costs equal $196,000 (439,000-109,000-134,000); and social feasibility
is not satisfied. Net social losses equal $30 for each ton recovered in
the basic scenario and convert to less than one cent per bottle for the
30 million twelve-ounce beer and soft-drink bottles "consumed" in Anchor-
age in 1979.
137
Since independent collectors no longer proc~ss or ship secondary
materials, the purchase price offered to them by the recovery v.Tholesaler
could be less than stateside secondary materials market prices and still
leave collectors better off. Note that the annual aggregate commercial
gain to collectors with centralized recovery wholesale services ($109,000)
is roughly equal in magnitude to the absolute value of coTh~ercial losses
in the basic scenario ($107,000). The commercial gain to collectors,
however, is less than one cent per pound collected. A lower price than
that assumed in Table 5-2 would lower collection incentives and jeopar-
dize recovery potential. Even if the quantity collected remains constant,
a lower price level results in a transfer of funds from one Ernup (thP
collectors) to another (the recovery wholesaler) such that no overall
net economic gain would result.
As shov,rn in Table 5-3, in addition to commercial profits and to
waste management benefits, $149,000 ih economic benefits accrue to
cnnP.lnnG<n; :and instj tuti nne; :1c; rA.c;h rPhAtPs for waste-separated secondary
materials.
Table 5-3. Economic Gains to Various Groups as a
Result of Recovery lffiolesale Services
Public or Private Gain
Waste Management System
Independent Collectors
Consumer and Institutional
Cash Rebate
Total Economic Gain
138
$130,000
109,000
149,000
$388,000
c
[
[~
L
F
tJ
h
L
l
In general, the relatively large net social costs ($196,000) sug-
gest that subsidization of a recovery '"holesaler Hill strongly depend
on the policy oakers' interpretation of amenity benefits and other non-
economic considerations.
Depletion deduction. To avoid the danger of concentrating public
assistance too narrov.1ly and thereby disrupting competitive relations
among recyclers, the State can modify existing tax policies to accom-
modate the ongoing financial needs of all recycling operations. I
explore potential impacts of tHo specific proposals for tax relief
based on recent national legislation (RPP AndPrson, lg77).
r
L
The first example consists of a deduction against taxable income
from recycling. It is analogous to the depletion allm,7 ance for primary
ra'"' material production. Deductions for secondary materials are com-
parable in magnitude to the depletion alloHance for the corresponding
primAry commodity and Hould be made available on some secondary materials
having renewable virgin counterparts (notably, waste paper). For example,
·deduction for waste paper is equal to 18 percent of taxable income.
Alternatively, the allowance could be constructed to reflect a por-
tion of the local or statewide public benefits from material recovery.
For example, the net public benefits (recall that public benefits are
distinguished from social benefits, which integrate both public and
~
L private sector costs and benefits) in the basic scenario equal $20.35
for each ton recovered. Public benefits per ton equal approximately
I =
L
139
23 percent of the average waste paper price per ton in the basic see-
nario. The depletion deduction could be set equal to 23 percent of
taxable income from waste paper recovery. The cost to the state would
depend on several factors, incl.uding the quantity recovery and the level
of taxable·income as determined by market prices and recovery costs.
I illustrate the potential cost of a 23 percent depletion deduction for
taxable income in connection with the previous example of aggregate
waste paper recovery by independent collectors. In this case, taxable
income is equal to $314,000 (463,000-149,000), of which about 63 percent
(by weight) or $198,000 accrues from waste paper collection. The deple-
tion deduction therefore equals $45,500, which represents about 60 percent
of total public benefits from waste paper recovery.
Tax credit. Credits against income tax liabilities could be granted
to collectors and recyclers that purchase secondary materials from users.
According to national legislative proposals (HR 10612), the tax credit
secondary material (subject to specified lower and upper bounds) and
would apply to production that exceeds 75 percent of a base-year level.
The following ''assumptions are used to estimate the cost to the
State of Alaska of a tax credit on waste paper recovery:
l.
2.
The base period level of waste paper recovery equals
my estimate of current annual waste paper recovery in
Anchorage--672 tons.
The tax credit is equal to ten percent of market price,
based on HR 10612.
140
[
[
n
[
n L,
[
F EJ
~
L
[
r
b
[
3. The quantity of v.Taste paper recovery fo \.Jhich the tax
credit applies·is equal to recovery in the basic scenario
(4,172 tons) and is consistent ,,,ith assumed recovery in
the previous example of the depletion deduction.
Under these conditions, the tax credit would require $26,400 from the
state operating budget.
Tax credits, in contrast to depletion deductions, would apply only
to profitable operations that incur income tax liabilities. Nonprofit
operators would, therefore, not benefit from a tax credit policy.
Further, \.Jhile tax relief protects the interests of some recyclers,
it does not correct the more complex problem of discriminatory tax regu-
lations and of traditional accounting practices that distort production
decisions in favor of primary commodity producing segments. That is,
resource misallocation will persist, although a more favorable balance
between primary and secondary comn1odity production might be achieved.
Tax relief measures, as well as direct subsidies, encourage the
development of and entry into the recycling recovery sector but do not
directly address the more fundamental issue of citizen participation.
Their impact on supply creation is, instead, indirect and occurs only to
the extent that these policies encourage collectors themselves to develop
stimulants for citizen participation in waste separation. For example,
Anderson (1977) estimates that the depletion deduction and the tax
credit proposals would increase national waste paper recycling between
1.4 and 1.6 percent, respectively.
141
The impact of tax relief on the quantity of sEcondary material
recovery in Alaska is unclear. On the one hand, tax relief redistrib-
utes a moderate portion of public benefits to the recycling recovery
sector~ Tax relief, however, ?oes not affect public participation
directly and may not reduce operating costs enough to permit decen-
tralized recovery by independent, small-scale recyclers to successfully
incorporate less profitable secondary materials. Tax relief may best
be used as an ancillary proposal in conjunction 1-1ith other more direct
recycling policies.
Community Participation
11-lo final policy proposals are considered. They are distinguished
from previous policies in that they address the problem of participation
in residential and institutional sectors directly.
Compulsory office paper separation. The first policy I consider
is compuls0ry ~PpArRti 0n Ann r0ll Prti nn nf hi p;h-grAne offir.e waste
paper. In the earlier discussion of office paper, high-grade separation
in the "buyback-plus-office-paper" scenario, I conservatively estimated
that upwards of 1,000 tons of high-grade white and colored ledger paper,
valued at more than $150,000, is recoverable from federal, state,· and
local government agencies in Anchorage (excluding military). An addi-
tional 1,000 tons of recoverable CPO and tab cards are also available
from all levels of government, plus commercial institutions (excluding
military). (See Table 2-4.)
142
[
[
c
[
[
R [~
,-:
Ll
~
L
i ~ w
H
[J
~
L
~~
I I-
L
The impact of office ledger and computer piper recovery from state
offices alone would more than double current waste paper recovery in
Anchorage. £-lore importantly, by increasing the level of overall tonnage
recycled, compulsory office pa~er separation would generate positive
economies Df scale in material recovery. In addition to reducing unit
recovery costs, we note that the impact of office collection over the
preceding buy-back scenario would raise net social benefits from $37
to $39 per ton (Table 4-18).
The total cost of office paper separation to the state would depend
on whether or not office paper is purchased by or donated to recyclers.
Under a buy-back program, the state vmuld recoup $15,000 annually \vhich
would cover from one-third to one-half of initial start-up equipment,
consisting of paper-separation desk trays and bulk containers for offices.
Under the assumption that the burden of paper separation on office
employees is negligible, the only remaining cost consideration concerns
contract modifications with janitorial services to handle office paper
separately from other mixed office waste.
Returnable beverage container legislation. Returnable beverage
container legislation (RBCL) establishes a refund value on most beverage
bottles and cans and requires distributors and grocers to redeem from,
customers, beverage containers they normally handle. In some cases
(e.g., the Alaska bottle bill initiative, 1978), containers not subject
to a. mandatory deposit would have to be reuonble, recyclable, or biode-
gradable. Other provisions that are common to RBCL establish standardized
143
containers for interchangeable use by several manufacturers, prohibit
detachable "pull tops,11 and call for creation of redemption centers
t..rhere c:ustomers may return empty heverage containers (e. g., Oregon
bottle bill, 1972).
Also knovm. as "mandatory deposit legislation," RBCL is not a direct
form of compulsory recycling but does create strong economic incentives
that encourage citizen participation in material recovery. RBCL is
currently in effect in eight U.S. jurisdictions,3 three Canadian prov-
inces, Norway, and Sweden. In most cases, it receives strong public
support and participation with negligible disruption to economic activity
in the beverage and container industry. For example, the Oregon Department
of Environmental Quality (1977) claims that implementation of Oregon's
bottle bill in 1972 has resulted in higher rates of reuse and recycling,
energy savings, higher emplo)~ent, and a 72-83 percent reduction in
roadside litter.
According to Zalob (1979) a recent U.S. Environmental Agency Study
estimates that 3 percent of the nation's primary energy 11
••• could ·be
saved by switching to a total returnable/refillable bottle system.11 This
is equivalent to 42 million barrels of oil each year (Zalob, 1979).
Despite the direct effect on material recovery, litter reduction,
and energy conservation, the Washington State Recycling Association (WSRA)
3 Including: Oregon (1972), Vermont (1973), South Dakota (1973),
Michigan (1976), Maine (1976), Delaware (1978), Iowa (1978), and
Connecticut (1978).
144
[
[
[
r,
L
[
H
[J
h
L
l_~
l-.j
n u
[
n
b
p
E
f~ L
c:::-iticized a re:ce~1t returnc.ble bevErc.ge containe·r act as a partial solu-
tion to the overall problem of solid waste management, a solution that
would not arconrnodate the existing recycling recovery system in Washington.
According to the WSRA, about 400 independently o"med private profit
and nonprofit, full-line recycling centers in Hashington State depend
mainly on revenues from the collection and sale of bottles and cans.
Aluminum cans and refillable bottles are bought back from consumers,
sorted, warehoused, and marketed intact to bottlers and aluminum pro-
ducers. For example, in addition to recycling 220 tons of assorted
wQste paper, household aluminum (pie pans and foil), tin and aluminum
cans, and automobile batteries, Seattle Recycling, Inc. (SRI) handled
128,000 cases (480 tons) of sorted, locally produced, refillable beer
. 1 4 batt es. SRI pays customers a cash rebate of 25 and 50 cents for each
case of beer bottles delivered to SRI. The cash rebate, unlike a deposit,
represents an economic gain to beverage consumers which reduces the
tot~l initial purcha£R price nf thP hPVPTAfP anrl rnntainer.
The HSRA is concerned that RBCL would eliminate the economic faun-
dation on which \.Jashington 1 s established recycling system prospers by
redirecting revenue-producing bottles and cans through the state 1 s
grocery stores. More importantly, for those recyclers that do function
4 Refillable is distinguished from returnable. The State of Wash-
ington has no RBCL in effect. Refillable bottles, therefore, have no
deposit. Their value is determined in secondary glass and aluminum
markets.
145
as redemption centers, the deposit disbursements~ which (in contrast to
cash rebates) 1vould not represent a net economic gain to consumers,
-vmuld impose severe liquidity constraints on recyclers and 1vould reduce
5 operating margins by more than ?O percent.
Although beverage bottles and cans comprise between 3 and 6 percent
of total mixed solid waste, they represent important commodities to the
independent, full-line recycler as a result of an established refillable
container system in Washington state.
Thus, Jepeudiug on the initial conditions, RJJCL can reduce the
commercial gain of established beverage container recovery to both the
consumer and the recycler. Further, the potential decline in the over-
all commercial position of full-line recyclers that depend on revenues
ftom an established network of bottle and can recovery may cause a
reduction in recovery of less profitable materials previously supported
by high value bottle8 and cans.
Recent developments in the patterns of recycling in Oregon suggest
a trend toward specialization in glass and aluminum recycling recovery
5 under RBCL, the recycler performs the same handling and shipping
functions as under the established refillable, no-deposit system.
However, more funds are tied up in the deposit than in the cash rebate,
which increases the cost of operation. According to SRI, operating
margins would be reduced from 33-to-15 percent per case. Operating
margin is defined as gross receipts from sales minus the cost of mate-
rials purchased, divided by gross receipts. Under RBCL, gross receipts
and the cost of materials purchased would include the refundable deposit.
146
[
[
r
t
n
tj
I
L
L
systems. for example, in 1979, Smith and Hill S"ystems, Ltd., (S & H)
entered greater Portland area markets for secondary glass and aluminum.
S & H collects, processes, and ships all types of beverage containers,
including those captured under .oregon's RBCL. Returnable bottles and
cans redeemed by distributors are then sold to S & H, \·Jhere they are
sorted, crushed, shredded, and shipped to glass and aluminum producers.
Equipment and production techniques are geared toward large-scale material
recovery and represent the most up-to-date applications of recycling
technology. S & H is able to profitably integrate into the network of
material recovery through a combination of specialization and large-
scale production.
In contrast to S & H, the main objective of Portland Recycle Team
(PRT), a nonprofit, full-line recycle center, is to •~iden the scope of
material recovery to include commercially unattractive secondary materials.
For example, PRT focuses recovery effort on glass containers that are not
subject to mandatory deposit under Oregon's RBCL. Portland Recycle Team
collects and washes primary wine and cider bottles and resells them to
respective bottlers at substantial losses.6
Further, PRT is unable to compete with S & H in the quantity.of
returnable bottles and cans which it does recover. In November 1979,
the managers of S & H and PRT were negotiating the mutually advantageous
6 In 1978, PRT' s Bottle 1,;J'orks Division ::.r'-c.1.:rred losses equal to
$13,000, which increased to $30,000 in 1979.
14 7
transfer of an aluminum can collection contract held by PRT. The trans-
fer would increase the scale of S & H's aluminum recovery and reduce
losses incurred by PRT.7
Although conclusive evidence is not available, the experiences of
Portland Recycling Team, Smith and Hill Systems, Ltd., and Seattle
Recycling, Inc., suggest that Oregon's RBCL is responsible for a shift
in recycling effort toward large-scale, special-recovery techniques.
~~ile PRT--the largest full-line recycler in Portland--is unable to
successfully compete in markets for secondary materials subsumed in
RBCL, SRI·· having comparable product mix, quantity, and composition to
that of PRT--identifies aluminum cans and refillable bottles as its
strongest revenue generating components.
Proximity to secondary materials markets is an important difference
between recyclers in the Pacific Northwest and in Alaska. The basic
recycling scen~rio pre~Pnted above &hnwed that, under conditions of
25 percent participation, commercial standards for glass recovery are
·not satisfied. According to the revenue and cost data in Table 4-8, a
break-even level of glass recovery is unattainable.8 It is therefore
unlikely that commercial recyclers would undertake glass recovery.
7 PRT ¥as unable to collect a sufficient volume of aluminum cans
to generate a positive return in that segment of material recovery.
8Note that variable operating costs per ton exceed revenue per ton.
Thus, losses increase with increases in tonnage unless unit variable
operating costs decrease with expanded recovery.
148
[
[
[
l
~~
L
r , u
~
L
L
L
r
L
[
L
On the other hand, positive net social beneFits in glass recovery
justify the implementation of a mandatory deposit system under the
assumption that basic scenario collection, processing, and freight costs
reflect aggregate costs of RBCL. to grocers, distributors, and recyclers
. h . 9 ln t e prlvate sector. Returnable beverage container legislation may
be the only practical solution to mobilizing glass recovery in Anchorage,
and elsewhere in Alaska.
RBCL may encourage the kind of large-scale, specialized recovery
exemplified by Smith and Hill Systems, Ltd. At 25 percent participation,
the difference bet,,reen revenue and cnst fnr cnmhinPf! e;l Ass hnttl e ;:mo
aluminum can recovery is positive in the basic scenario. Although not
reflected in basic scenario data, it is possible (and likely) that a
scale of glass recovery that exceeds 25 percent would lower unit vari-
able costs of recovery and provide additional incentive for commercial
involvement in glass recycling recovery systems.
More importantly, since used glass is presently not recovered for
any form of recycling in Anchorage and since the quantity of current ·
aluminum collection represents only six percent of feasible recovery,
RBCL should not interfere with present Anchorage-based recycling e·ffort.
9 Basic scenario glass recovery costs do not capture the extra ware-
housing costs to grocers and distributors in stockpiling and transferring
glass bottles to the recycler and may therefore understate com..'1lercial
losses and overstate net social benefits.
149
[
Suoo!larv
The public policy response to R lRrge, nnexploited rf'serve of
secondary-materials and to a re.cycling recovery system that includes
several independent, small-scale recyclers must be taylored to circum-[
stances and problems unique to Alaska and to the domestic and inter-
national recycling industry as a whole. The primary constraint to the [
developmen.t of local recycling recovery systems is Alaska's distant [ proximity to secondary materials markets.
In the preceding discussion, I reviewed several public policies
to stimulate material recovery for recycling. The type of policies r
L
examined include subsidies, tax relief, and compulsory measures. [
Policy measures therefore affect secondary material recovery
directly by stimulating community participation in waste separation and
indirectly by strengthening the reryrling rernvery ~ertnr (i.e., srrAp ~ ' .
collectors and recycle centers) which, in turn, develops its own eco-
nomic or information incentives to encourage community involvement in
waste separation.
Policy measures that strengthen recovery sector activity include
direct subsidization, depletion deductions on taxable income, and tax
credits. Direct subsidization is capable of stimulating the recovery of
less profitable secondary materials but constitutes a form of direct lri
L
r·
'---·-'
150
n
b
R 1:]
~ L
r-
public intervention in privc.te markets that discriminates against exist-
ing independent profit and nonprofit recyclers. Attempts to spread the
impact of public assistance may not fully eliminate thjs effect and
reduce the opportunity for rec~very of commercially less favorable mate-
rials (e.g·., glass, mixed scrap paper, and corrugated containers).
1--'e examined the implications of a publicly funded "central recovery
wholesaler" as an alternative to direct subsidization. As an interme-
diary between independent Anchorage-based collectors and "stateside"
dealers, the recovery wholesaler would preserve competition, "'ould avoid
the problem of grant discrimination, and would achieve greater economies
of scale in first-stage processing and shipping. Although noticeable
gains would accrue to commercial collectors, the provision of recovery
wholesale services would require plant and equipment outlays and ongoing
e:kpenses that exceed combined measures of private and public benefits.
Depletion deductions and tax credits are indirect subsidies that
benefit some, but not all, recyclers.
Compulsory office paper separation and returnable beverage con-
tainer legislation ?(RBCL) affect community participation directly.· RBCL
directs glass bottle and aluminum recovery to the grocer and distributor;
replaces consumer cash rebates with refundable deposits; and, under cer-
tain conditions, reduces the potential return to recyclers. Recent
developments in Oregon's recycling industry suggest that, in contrast to
full-line recycling, large-scale, specialized recycling recovery systems
151
may best accommodate RBCL. However, in Alaska, used glass is unlikely
to enter the product mix of the full-line recycler. Consequently, RBCL
may provide the institutional framework to mobilize a form of material
recovery ·that would not otherw~se develop in the commercial sector.
[
Compulsory separation and collection of state office waste paper
would provide an immediate source of waste paper supply to recyclers [
with negligible public intervention in private sector markets. Office
paper separation implies a host of management and logistics problems l
which, like other policy measures, would require attention and commitment
oa LlH:! lJi:iLL vf several grvuvs, es}Jeclally lu Ll1e lulllal slages.
In conclusion, I would like to_stress four general factors in the
development policy to stimulate private and public sector involvement L
in recycling. First, the recycling industry is unusually sensitive to
events which induce even slight changes in market conditions or in tech-
nology. Rncnll that secondary materials are generated from commodities
produced in earlier periods and are therefore affected by factors which
·influence the quantity and physical characteristics of primary commodities.
Additionally, secondary materials compete in markets for primary materials
from which they are originally produced (e.g., waste paper and wood pulp).
Thus, to avoid unintended disruptions in the recycling industry, public
policy should minimize the extent of direct intervention in the private
sector. That is, policy makers should avoid regulatory policies and
institutional impediments that compete with or discriminate against ~
L
independent recyclers in the private sector.
f
·:_
·-.
152
Q
=
~~
L
r
l
L
Second) corr~unity participation is the key ·to effective development
of used materials supplies for market exchange. It is likely that in
view of rising demand in most used materials markets) the recycling
recovery sector will respond i~ tandum to forthcoming secondary material
supplies from residential and commercial sources.
In the absence of economic incentives, however, changes in consumer
"throwaway" attitudes would be unlikely. As we have seen, although con-
servative estimates of direct social benefits to the local community
from material recovery are large, they are not reflected in market
prices. Market prices, therefore, understate the rcul vuluc of recycling
to society and neither the recycling recovery sector nor the residential
and institutional community receive adequate economic incentives to
expand material recovery.
Legislative initiative is requir'ed to expose "hidden" economic
benefits in order to stimulate partjcipation in several sectors of the
economy.
Third, better information is needed in all sectors of the economy.
The state can facilitate information improvements by establishing·an
information exchartge system which circulates technical and market infer-
mation and provides a source for feedback from consumers and recyclers.
·An example is the state-funded "Recycling Hot Line" in Oregon.
153
Fourth, the importance of non-economic factors as criteria for
evaluating policy proposals should not be overlooked. The assumptions
used throughout this report tend to be conservative (even under optimistic
conditions), so that the net sqcial benefits corresponding to specific
recycling scenarios are understated just as net social costs are over-
stated. The aesthetic benefit in reduced pollution and roadside litter
is perhaps the most important unquantified benefit of recycling. There-
fore, in ~ddition to economic criteria, policies to stimulate recycling
should be ranked according to qualitative public benefits and costs.
For example, given two policies that both would achieve net social
benefits, the policy having greater total recovery or greater recovery
of more environmentally damaging materials would be selected regardless
of comparative rankings of net social benefits.
154
fl
[
L
[
n D
f ~
L
[
r
b
BIBLIOGR....IU'h'Y
ACLW and M&E, Inc., Consulting Engineers. Study of On-Site Storage,
Collection, and Bulk Transportation of Solid Wastes. Prepared
for the Greater Anchorage Area Borough Public Works Department,
Solid Haste Management Division, [1973].
Anderson, Robert C. "Public Policies Toward the Use of Scrap Materials."
American Economic Review 67 (February 1977): 355-8.
"Recycling Policy-Basic Economic Issues," in Resource
Conservation: Social and Economic Dimensions of Recycling.
ed. David W. Pearce and Ingo Walter. New York: New York
University Press, 1977.
Bomhoff and Associates, Inc. Solid Waste Management Processing and
Disposal Study. Prepared for the Greater Anchorage Area Borough
Public Harks Department, Solid \\faste Management Division, [1975].
Darnay, Arsen and Franklin, E. William. Salvage Markets for Materials
in Solid \.Jaste. Kansas City: Midwest Research Institute, [1972].
Ender, Richard L; Gehler, Jan; Gorski, Susan; and Harper, Susan.
Anchorage Socioeconomic and Physical Baseline: Technical Report
Number 12. Anchorage: Bureau of Land ~1anagement, Alaska Outer
Continental Shelf Office, [1978].
Gray, John T.
Institute
[1979].
Transportation Systems Planning for Alaska. Anchorage:
of Social and Economic· Research, University of Alaska,
Greater Anchorage Area Borough.
Master Plan. Public \\forks
Division, [1975] .
Preliminary Solid \\Taste Management
Department, Solid Haste Management
. Hayes, D€mnis. Repairs, Reuse, Recycling -First Steps Toward a Sus-
tainable Societv. Horldwatch Paper 23, 1978.
Metcalf and Eddy Ertgineers. Feasibility of Resource Recovery from
Solid Waste. Anchorage: Public Works Department, Division of
Solid Waste Management, [1979].
Nebesky, William E. "A Simultaneous Equation Model of the Domestic
Market for Waste Paper," M.S. Thesis, University of Wisconsin,
1979.
Portland Recycling Team. Resource Conservation Through Citizen Involve-
ment in Waste Management. Portland: Metropolitan Service District,
[1975].
155
Quimby, Thomas H. E. Recycling: The Alternative to Disposal. Baltimore:
John Hopkins.University Press, 1975.
Resource Conservation Consultants, Inc.
tion Industry in Portland, Oregon.
1979.
An Analysis of the l\1aste Collec-
Portland: Teamsters Local 281,
Schwegler, Ronald E. Solid t.Jastes Facts. Washington: Institute for
Solid'Wastes, [1978).
Seattle Recycling, Inc. Final Report for the Sort Project. Seattle:
Solid Waste Utility, [1979].
Tania, Lipshutz. Garbage-to-Energy: The False Panacea. Santa Rosa:
Sonoma County Community Recycling Center, [1979).
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Resource Recovery and Waste
Reduction. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office,
[1915).
Zalob, David S.
Recycling:
Journal 19
"Current Legislation and Practice of Compulsory
An International Perspective." Natural Resources
(July 1979): 611-28.
156
AP~IS
Alaska Resources
Library & Information Services
Anchorage Alaska
·[
~--
'
I
[_.
r
..
_,
[
n LJ
R
L
r ;
l ,